Blog postings by CEPR staff and updates on the latest briefings and activities at the Center for Economic and Policy Research.

Representative Peter DeFazio (D-OR) recently introduced a new bill (H.R. 5745), “Putting Main Street FIRST: Finishing Irresponsible Reckless Speculative Trading Act.” The purpose of the bill is to curb high-volume speculative trading. In the bill, this is accomplished by imposing a small tax on financial trades.

The tax, known as a Financial Transactions Tax (FTT) or Wall Street Speculation Tax (WST), would be assessed at 3 basis points, or just 3 cents per every 100 dollars traded. The tax would primarily impact traders and suppliers of financial services. The main effect for consumers is that they would spend less in total trading costs, as they reduce trading volume in response to the tax.

At 3 basis points, the revenue would be $417 billion in revenue over the next decade according to the latest estimates of the Joint Committee on Taxation (JCT). Just as importantly, the tax could increase the efficiency of the financial sector.

Add a comment

Tonight, Governor Scott Walker will speak at the GOP Convention supporting his former rival, Donald Trump. As the Governor makes the case for the Republican nominee, it is worth assessing Walker’s record in his more than 5 years in Wisconsin.

During his time as governor, Wisconsin has been a laboratory for many Republican economic policies. Walker cut taxes by more than $4.7 billion, stripped state employees of collective bargaining rights, and deregulated industry. The Republican Party platform calls for similar polices on the national level, making promises to cut taxes and reduce regulatory barriers.

At the same Governor Walker took office in Wisconsin in 2010, Mark Dayton, a liberal Democrat took office in neighboring Minnesota. The relative performances of the two states provide a simple and interesting test of their differing agendas.

Add a comment

To what extent has the age of globalization benefited developing countries—and what of the poor in those countries? To what extent has such progress been driven by local policy decisions rather than a more global phenomenon? Has such development come alongside stagnation of poor and middle incomes within more developed countries and large benefited the extremely rich?

One way—however incomplete—to begin an investigation would be to look at the global “growth incidence curve” (GIC) of Lakner and Milanovic. They estimate the worldwide distributions of income in both 1988 and 2008, which allows them to answer questions such as “How does median (the 50th percentile) income change between the two years.” The GIC is sometimes referred to as the “elephant curve” for its resemblance to the beast.

Add a comment

The Labor Department reported that the economy added 287,000 jobs in June, a sharp bounce back from the 11,000 jobs now reported for May. A big factor in the reversal was the end of the Verizon strike which subtracted 37,000 jobs from the May growth number and added the same amount to June, but even adjusting for this effect the June growth figure is much stronger.

The job gains were widely spread across sectors. Health care added 38,500 jobs, retail added 29,900, while the government sector added 22,000, with 17,000 at the local government level. Manufacturing added 14,000 jobs with 13,000 of these in food manufacturing. Construction was flat and mining lost another 6,400 jobs. 

The average hourly wage is 2.6 percent above its year-ago level. In the last three months, it has risen at a 2.7 percent annual rate compared with its level for the prior three months.

The household survey showed a bleaker picture. The unemployment rate rose modestly to 4.9 percent. The employment-to-population ratio (EPOP) fell to 59.6 percent as employment measured by the survey increased by just 67,000. Employment in the household survey is still more than 200,000 below its March level.

By demographic group the most disturbing item is the reported rise in the unemployment rate among black teens to 31.2 percent. It had been 23.3 percent in February. These data are highly erratic, but the trend is large enough that it could reflect a substantial deterioration in the labor market.

Employment patterns by education are showing an interesting pattern in this recovery. Over the last year the unemployment rate for college grads has not changed while their EPOP is down by 0.3 pp. By contrast, the unemployment rate for those with a high school degree has fallen by 0.4 pp and by 0.6 pp for those with less than a high school degree. The increased demand for skills is not obvious in this picture.

Add a comment

Since the Fed first announced its 2 percent inflation target on January 25, 2012, inflation has consistently run too low. In fact, the Fed has undershot its target in 48 of the 51 months since its announcement. 

The most recent data from the Consumer Price Index (CPI) show that inflation over the past year has been just 1.0 percentPart of this weakness is due to the volatile energy (down 10.1 percent from one year ago) and food (up 0.7 percent) aspects of the index. The Fed typically pulls out these components and looks at the core CPI. This measure shows a somewhat higher rate of inflation with a modest increase over the last year.

Add a comment

The following highlights CEPR’s latest research, publications, events, and much more for June.

CEPR on Brexit

CEPR was a key voice weighing in on the decision by UK voters to leave the European Union, both before and after the June 23rd referendum. CEPR Co-Director Mark Weisbrot appeared on the Diane Rehm show prior to the vote, and he wrote a piece for The Hill titled “Should I Stay or Should I Go? Brexit, Extortion, and the Path to Reform.”

After the vote was decided, Mark issued this press release following the announcement that a majority of UK voters had chosen to leave the UK. He also wrote a post on possible foreign policy outcomes of the Brexit vote for his World in Transition blog titled “Always Look on the Bright Side of Life.”

CEPR Co-Director Dean Baker provided immediate feedback on Brexit with Lawrence O’Donnell’s breaking news segment and also appeared on MSNBC’s All in With Chris Hayes. He penned this article for the PBS NewsHour (which climbed to be one of their Top Five pieces) and he wrote numerous posts for his blog Beat the Press, both before and after the vote, including one titled“Paul Krugman, Brexit, and Unaccountable Government” (the remainder can be found herehereherehereherehereandhere). Dean was cited by Policy.Mic. He was also mentioned in this piece in the New Yorker that asked “What do the Brexit Movement and Donald Trump Have in Common?” and joined a handful of other experts in this Politico piecetitled “How Brexit Will Change the World.” 

Add a comment

This is the seventh in a series of profiles of the members of the Federal Reserve Board’s Open Market Committee [FOMC]. The profiles will focus on their writings, public statements, and voting records as members of the FOMC.

John Williams took over as President of the San Francisco Federal Reserve in March 2011, five months after Janet Yellen’s departure from the post. Williams, who previously served as Yellen’s director of research, is generally considered a moderate dove. He upholds the employment side of the Fed’s dual mandate and has consistently supported quantitative easing and a gradual path for interest rate normalization. The exception to Williams’ more dovish views is that he has called for rate hikes to begin at a relatively early date; however, this is largely because of Williams’ aforementioned support for a slow, gradual course of rate hikes.

Williams has published extensively on monetary policy. In 2006 — about two years before the Fed would reduce the federal funds interest rate to almost zero percent — Williams published a paper warning about the dangers of the zero lower bound (ZLB) on interest rates.[1] He found that the ZLB can be a significant constraint on monetary policy when the general public has imperfect knowledge of policy and the economy; in the paper’s conclusion, Williams noted that the ZLB placed greater emphasis on “the potential use of fiscal policy interventions,” i.e. deficit spending.[1]

Add a comment

In the 1970s, economist Arthur Okun coined the term “misery index.” The misery index was meant to calculate the amount of economic misery by adding the unemployment rate to the annual inflation rate. This treats a one percentage-point rise in the unemployment rate as being no worse than a one percentage rise in the inflation rate.

In a sense, the Federal Reserve actually adheres to a version of Okun’s misery index when setting monetary policy. As part of its dual mandate, the Fed pursues the twin goals of “maximum employment” and “stable prices.” While the mandate allows room for ambiguity, many Fed officials seem to assign greater importance to inflation than unemployment.

However, as Binyamin Appelbaum reported three years ago in The New York Times, consumer surveys from both the U.S. and Europe indicate that unemployment creates about four times as much misery as inflation. This result has been attested to in a host of academic studies (see pages 1–3).

A properly constructed misery index would therefore place four times as much weight on a one percentage point rise in the unemployment rate as on a one percentage point rise in the inflation rate. In terms of promoting well-being, an economy with low unemployment will usually beat an economy with low inflation.

Add a comment

This is the sixth in a series of profiles of the members of the Federal Reserve Board’s Open Market Committee [FOMC]. The profiles will focus on their writings, public statements, and voting records as members of the FOMC.

Unlike Esther GeorgeLoretta MesterEric RosengrenJames Bullard, and William Dudley first five members of the FOMC to be profiled by CEPR  Patrick Harker does not have an extensive background at the Federal ReserveHaving been officially appointed to head the Philadelphia Federal Reserve on July 1, 2015, Harker has been in office less than a year.[1] Moreover, as the President of the Philadelphia Fed, Harker will not serve as a voting member of the FOMC for the first time until 2017.[2] (The head of the Philadelphia Fed is given a vote once every three years.[2]) This means that Harker has no voting record and has only a short history of public statements on monetary policy.

Add a comment

Last month the International U.S. Trade Commission (ITC) came out with its assessment of the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP). It projected that in 2032, when the economy will have experienced most of the effects of the deal, income will be 0.23 percent higher than in a baseline without the TPP. This translates to an increase in the annual growth rate of 0.014 percentage point.

That is not the sort of thing that would likely get most people too excited. It means that with the TPP in place we will basically be as rich on January 1, 2032 as we would be in the middle of February of 2032 without the TPP. Still this is better than nothing, so why not take the gains the ITC is projecting?

The answer to that question is that the ITC projections are hardly a sure deal. Its past track record, like that of most modelers of trade agreements, has been pretty dismal. The actual patterns in trade have born essentially no relationship to the projected patterns.

This may be due to the possibility that the impact of factors not included in the models swamped the projected impact of the changes being modeled. That’s an argument that can save the validity of the models used by the ITC and other economists, but doesn’t change the fact that these models have not been useful guides to the future course of trade and economic growth.

Add a comment

CEPR recently released a blog post titled “Maximum Potential Employment and the Jobs Gap.” The post asked two simple questions:

  • 1. How high could the employment rate go given the current age composition of the population?

  • 2. How large is the gap between this potential employment rate and the actual employment rate?

The post concluded that although the gap between actual and potential employment has declined since the end of the recession, it is nonetheless larger than it was before the recession.

The “maximum potential employment rate” used in the post was calculated by asking what the overall employment rate would be if each age group were to achieve its highest calendar-year employment rate at the same time. It is notable that the current jobs gap is due purely to low employment rates among younger workers. With the exceptions of the 45–49 and 70+ age groups, there is a consistent rule to be had in terms of job loss: employment has declined more significantly for younger workers than for older workers.

Add a comment

Legislators in the United States have been reluctant to tax the highest income tax-payers at higher rates. “Millionaire taxes,” through the addition of higher marginal income tax rates on income over $1 million, exist only in one state, California. Connecticut taxes married couples with combined incomes over $1 million at a higher rate as well. At the federal level, the top income tax bracket starts at $415,051 for individuals and at $466,950 for couples. Despite growing income inequality and calls for the rich to pay more, there has been little to no political will to increase tax rates on incomes over $1 million.

One rationale often used to explain this reluctance is the belief that higher tax rates on the rich would lead to an exodus of high-income tax payers. When President François Hollande proposed a 75% tax rate on incomes over 1 million euros, commentators around the world predicted mass out migration of high income French citizens. The mass emigration failed to occur during the two year duration of the higher rate, but the higher tax bracket was quietly allowed to expire at the end of 2014.

Add a comment

That’s right, CEPR Co-director Mark Weisbrot is now blogging at CEPR.net!

His new blog on economic and political trends in a multi-polar world debuted this past month. “The World in Transition: Economics and Politics” has featured several posts already, including this one on the Democratic primary, this one on political judiciary in Argentina, and this analysis of the IMF’s estimates of potential GDP and Nouriel Roubini’s forecasts for the global economy. Mark also wrote posts on Brazil, including this one on leaked conversations that reveal major players colluded to carry out the coup, and this one on the coup and Washington’s “rollback” of the left in Latin America.

Want more? Mark needs your support to continue

Add a comment

The data in the Job Openings and Labor Turnover Survey (JOLTS) provide evidence of continuing weakness in the labor market in spite of the relatively low unemployment rate.

Through the first three months of 2016, the unemployment rate averaged 4.95 percent. While this is a reasonably low unemployment rate, by many other measures the labor market is far from recovering from the recession. One of these measures is the quits rate.

When workers feel that there are few job opportunities, they are less likely to quit their jobs, because they see few better opportunities. Through the first three months of the year, the quits rate has averaged just 2.04 percent, an unusually low rate.

Add a comment

The Labor Department reported that the economy created just 38,000 new jobs in May, the weakest job growth since September of 2010, when it lost 52,000 jobs. In addition, the jobs numbers for the prior two months were revised down by 59,000, bringing the average for the last three months to just 116,000.

The household survey showed a drop of 0.3 percentage points in the unemployment rate, but this is not especially good news. The decline was almost entirely due to people leaving the labor force. The employment-to-population ratio [EPOP] was unchanged at 59.7 percent, 0.2 percentage points below the the peak for the recovery. In addition, the number of people involuntarily working part-time jumped by 468,000.

Add a comment

According to many economists, the economy is at or near its full employment level of output; see, for example, the San Francisco Federal Reserve President’s recent comments. Those of us who dispute this contention point to data points like the unusually high share of the workforce that is working part-time involuntarily or the unusually low quit rates. The current levels for these and other commonly used measures of labor market tightness are not consistent with full employment.

But the most important reason that we are reluctant to accept that the economy is at full employment is that a much smaller share of prime-age workers (ages 25–54) are employed today than at the business cycle peaks in 2007 and 2000. For men, the employment to population (EPOP) ratio is down by more than 3.0 percentage points from the 2007 peaks and by more than 4.5 percentage points from the 2000 peaks. For women, the drop is 2.0 percentage points against the 2007 peak and more than 4.0 percentage points against the 2000 peak.  

Those proclaiming full employment dismiss these numbers and attribute them to longer term, non-cyclical, trends. The problem is that the data don’t fit prior trends. Before 2000, the EPOP ratio for prime-age men was on a very gradual downward trend. It dropped 0.9 percentage points from the business cycle peak in 1989 to 2000, 11 years later, a rate of less than 0.1 percentage points per year. For women, there was a continual upward trend through 2000; the EPOP ratio gained over 3.0 percentage points since 1989, or roughly 0.3 percentage points per year.

But the recession in 2001 pushed down the EPOP ratio for both men and women, and neither has ever recovered. The Great Recession in 2007–2009 was another severe hit on top of that.  

Add a comment

The 2008 recession caused job losses across the board, but it was especially hard for young Americans. The annual employment rate for 2024 year-olds declined 8.1 percentage points between 2007 and 2010; for 2529 year-olds, employment fell 6.0 percentage points through 2011. As of 2015, employment was still down 4.6 percentage points for the former group and 3.1 percentage points for the latter.

By contrast, employment among seniors did not fall during the recession it actually increased. Between 2006 and 2015, there was not a single year in which employment fell for Americans age 65 and over. Employment in this age group is up 2.7 percentage points since 2007 and is up 3.2 percentage points since 2006.

Add a comment

In 2007, the employment rate – the percentage of all Americans 16 and older who have a job – averaged 63.0 percent. The rate fell as low as 58.2 percent during the recession, and has since recovered to just 59.7 percent.

There are significant questions about how much of the drop reflects weakness in the economy as opposed to just an aging population. Between 2007 and 2015, the share of the population aged 25 to 54 – the ages when we expect people to be employed – fell from 54 to 50 percent. Over the same period, the share of the population 55 and older increased 5 percentage points from 30 to 35 percent.

However, it’s also the case that employment has fallen within most age groups. The employment rate of the 25-54 population dropped 5.2 percentage points during the recession and has risen just 3.0 percentage points since then. The employment rate for 55-64 year-olds is close to where it was before the recession, while the employment rate of Americans 65 and older is actually up.

We are not left with an “either-or” proposition. The employment rate has fallen due to cyclical weakness and the aging of the population. So it’s worth asking: how much higher could the employment rate be given the demographic composition of the population?

Add a comment

This is a bonus blog post in a series of profiles of the members of the Federal Reserve Board’s Open Market Committee [FOMC]. The profiles focus on their writings, public statements, and voting records as members of the FOMC.

Last Monday, CEPR released a FedWatch piece on William Dudley’s views on monetary policy. Dudley is the head of the New York Federal Reserve (one of the Fed’s 12 regional banks) and the Vice-Chairman of the FOMC. The New York Fed is different from the other regional banks because, along with fulfilling normal regional bank functions, it also serves as a regulator of the Wall Street banks.

As part of CEPR’s ongoing FedWatch series looking at the views of FOMC members, we are releasing an extra “bonus” post examining Dudley’s views on the financial sector.

Add a comment

The United States International Trade Commission (USITC) recently came out with projections on the economic effects of the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) trade deal. The USITC’s report is the third major study on the TPP from the past two years. The USITC is legally required to provide this report.

The USITC report shows that the TPP would have relatively little impact on the volume of trade. This is consistent with the projections from a study by the United States Department of Agriculture (USDA) (which only examined the impact on agriculture), but is far out of line with the projections by the Peterson Institute for International Economics, the producer of the third major study.

Add a comment

This is the fourth in a series of profiles of the members of the Federal Reserve Board’s Open Market Committee [FOMC]. The profiles will focus on their writings, public statements, and voting records as members of the FOMC.

Since assuming office in January 2009, New York Federal Reserve Bank President William Dudley has been considered one of the Fed’s more dovish members. With some exceptions, Dudley has generally been a supporter of stimulus measures such as quantitative easing (QE) and low interest rates.

In a November 2010 New York Times article titled Under Attack, Fed Officials Defend Buying of Bonds, Dudley argued that QE was lowering long-term interest rates and raising employment.[1] He also said that high inflation was a non-existent problem and that policymakers should be worried instead about deflation.[1] In a speech the previous month, Dudley stated that “low and falling inflation is a problem for several reasons,” most notably because low inflation makes it hard for borrowers to pay off their debts and because low inflation in the short-term leads to declining expectations for future inflation.[2] The latter factor, he argued, can actually push down present inflation.[2] In discussing a possible drop in inflation expectations, Dudley made it clear that he viewed joblessness as a far more significant problem than inflation:

“Such a tightening would clearly be highly undesirable at a moment when unemployment is too high, inflation is too low and the economy has only moderate forward momentum.”[2]

Dudley also went on to state that “inflation being ‘too low’ (just like inflation being ‘too high’) is an impediment to achieving the full employment objective of the [Fed's] dual mandate.”[2] He furthermore argued that if the Fed were to target a given rate of inflation (it was not targeting 2 percent inflation at the time of Dudley’s speech), it should allow the economy to go over the target inflation rate for a given period of time in order to offset the time spent below the target rate.[2] Dudley continued making these same arguments in 2011, stating that the Fed shouldn’t withdraw monetary stimulus, as such a move would hinder the Fed’s dual mandate of full employment and price stability.[3] He reiterated that inflation was running problematically low and said that the labor market was well short of full employment; he also stated that in order to return to full employment in 2012, the economy would have to add 300,000 jobs per month.[3]

Add a comment