Beat the Press

Beat the press por Dean Baker

Beat the Press is Dean Baker's commentary on economic reporting. He is a Senior Economist at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR). To never miss a post, subscribe to a weekly email roundup of Beat the Press. Please also consider supporting the blog on Patreon.

The NYT ran a piece on the new Congressional Budget Office estimates of the cost and coverage rates for the Affordable Care Act following the changes required by the Supreme Court ruling. It concluded the piece with a classic he said/she said:

“Representative Tom Price of Georgia, chairman of the House Republican Policy Committee, said the law was unaffordable, and he pointed to the $1.7 trillion price tag mentioned by the budget office.

But Representative Allyson Y. Schwartz, Democrat of Pennsylvania, said the law was a good deal that would ‘save $109 billion over the next decade, while increasing access to health care for millions of Americans.'”

Well that settles it, the paper has done its job.

How about telling us how large this sum is relative to projected income (about 0.85 percent)? How about as a share of projected federal spending (about  4.0 percent)? Maybe the paper could compare to the size of the tax cuts proposed by governor Romney (less than 50 percent)?

The he said/she said at the end of this piece is killing trees for nothing. It provides no useful information to readers. (We already knew that Republicans didn’t like the plan and Democrats do.)  It would have required minimal effort to put these numbers in a context that provided useful information to readers.

The NYT ran a piece on the new Congressional Budget Office estimates of the cost and coverage rates for the Affordable Care Act following the changes required by the Supreme Court ruling. It concluded the piece with a classic he said/she said:

“Representative Tom Price of Georgia, chairman of the House Republican Policy Committee, said the law was unaffordable, and he pointed to the $1.7 trillion price tag mentioned by the budget office.

But Representative Allyson Y. Schwartz, Democrat of Pennsylvania, said the law was a good deal that would ‘save $109 billion over the next decade, while increasing access to health care for millions of Americans.'”

Well that settles it, the paper has done its job.

How about telling us how large this sum is relative to projected income (about 0.85 percent)? How about as a share of projected federal spending (about  4.0 percent)? Maybe the paper could compare to the size of the tax cuts proposed by governor Romney (less than 50 percent)?

The he said/she said at the end of this piece is killing trees for nothing. It provides no useful information to readers. (We already knew that Republicans didn’t like the plan and Democrats do.)  It would have required minimal effort to put these numbers in a context that provided useful information to readers.

Robert Samuelson’s column lays out the factors that caused the huge surplus predicted for the last decade by the Congressional Budget Office to turn into a huge deficit. Samuelson cites analysis of the $12 trillion shift from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and two “non-partisan” groups, the Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget and the Pew Fiscal Initiative.

Samuelson and these groups are careful to say that blame for this shift is widely shared, but that the largest chunk stems from weaker than projected economic growth and changes in technical assumptions. If we look more closely at the weaker than expected economic growth and some of those technical assumptions, the picture gets a bit more interesting.

The economy grew much more slowly than expected in 2001 and 2002 because of the collapse of a stock bubble. It grew much less rapidly than expected in 2008 and 2009 because of a collapse of the housing bubble. Some of the “technical changes” were the result of much lower capital gains income than had been projected. That is what happens when a bubble bursts. (The official data probably understates the falloff, since it is likely that much capital gains income shows up as normal income.)

In short, the main reason that the CBO projections understated the deficits over the last decade was that it twice failed to recognize asset bubbles. In fact, the impact of this failure on projections is even larger since some items on the Samuelson deficit list would not have been there absent the slower growth, like the Obama stimulus.

So there is a clear villain in this story, economic analysts who were too incompetent to recognize two huge bubbles and the impact that their collapse would have on the economy. Unfortunately, in Washington policy circles, such failures are a badge of honor (“who could have known?” is the official motto in these parts), so these folks continue to hold their jobs and get regular promotions and increased authority.

While we might prefer to see people with better knowledge of the economy in positions of responsibility, there is a bright side. These jobs keep people without marketable skills employed.

Robert Samuelson’s column lays out the factors that caused the huge surplus predicted for the last decade by the Congressional Budget Office to turn into a huge deficit. Samuelson cites analysis of the $12 trillion shift from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) and two “non-partisan” groups, the Committee for a Responsible Federal Budget and the Pew Fiscal Initiative.

Samuelson and these groups are careful to say that blame for this shift is widely shared, but that the largest chunk stems from weaker than projected economic growth and changes in technical assumptions. If we look more closely at the weaker than expected economic growth and some of those technical assumptions, the picture gets a bit more interesting.

The economy grew much more slowly than expected in 2001 and 2002 because of the collapse of a stock bubble. It grew much less rapidly than expected in 2008 and 2009 because of a collapse of the housing bubble. Some of the “technical changes” were the result of much lower capital gains income than had been projected. That is what happens when a bubble bursts. (The official data probably understates the falloff, since it is likely that much capital gains income shows up as normal income.)

In short, the main reason that the CBO projections understated the deficits over the last decade was that it twice failed to recognize asset bubbles. In fact, the impact of this failure on projections is even larger since some items on the Samuelson deficit list would not have been there absent the slower growth, like the Obama stimulus.

So there is a clear villain in this story, economic analysts who were too incompetent to recognize two huge bubbles and the impact that their collapse would have on the economy. Unfortunately, in Washington policy circles, such failures are a badge of honor (“who could have known?” is the official motto in these parts), so these folks continue to hold their jobs and get regular promotions and increased authority.

While we might prefer to see people with better knowledge of the economy in positions of responsibility, there is a bright side. These jobs keep people without marketable skills employed.

Reuters must be trying to win a Pulitzer in the bad business reporting category (sorry folks, you’ve got some stiff competition). The headline of a piece on the Commerce Department’s report on new home sales for June warned of the largest drop in sales more than a year. Are you scared?

If you look at the data, you would notice that May had one of the biggest jumps in sales in the last year, raising the rate to the highest level since the fall of 2008. Furthermore, three quarters of the drop was explained by a 60 percent decline in new homes sales in the Northeast. That could be real, but my guess is that this is some artifact of reporting that will be corrected when these numbers are revised next month. (I have not heard about the collapse of the economies in in NY, NJ, and MA.)

A little context would be helpful on this one. If May and June’s sales are averaged, we would be seeing a strong uptick in sales compared to earlier this year.

Reuters must be trying to win a Pulitzer in the bad business reporting category (sorry folks, you’ve got some stiff competition). The headline of a piece on the Commerce Department’s report on new home sales for June warned of the largest drop in sales more than a year. Are you scared?

If you look at the data, you would notice that May had one of the biggest jumps in sales in the last year, raising the rate to the highest level since the fall of 2008. Furthermore, three quarters of the drop was explained by a 60 percent decline in new homes sales in the Northeast. That could be real, but my guess is that this is some artifact of reporting that will be corrected when these numbers are revised next month. (I have not heard about the collapse of the economies in in NY, NJ, and MA.)

A little context would be helpful on this one. If May and June’s sales are averaged, we would be seeing a strong uptick in sales compared to earlier this year.

As noted previously, the Washington Post has a huge stake in saying that NAFTA was a success. As a result, it simply cannot honestly discuss the state of Mexico’s economy in either its news or opinion pages. Today it has a piece that is headlined on the main page of its web site as “Mexico’s middle class begins to boom.” Readers would never know that Mexico has had the worst growth record in all of Latin America over the last decade.

Since the Post seems intent on recycling misleading news stories, I will recycle my comments. The segment below is from July 1 of this year:

The Washington Post Still Can’t Talk Honestly About Mexico’s Economy

The Washington Post is heavily invested in NAFTA. At the time of the debate it abandoned any pretext of being an objective newspaper, allowing both its opinion and news pages to be overwhelmingly dominated by proponents of the agreement. Since its passage the Post has refused to acknowledge that the agreement has had the intended effect in the United States of lowering the wages of manufacturing workers. (This is textbook economics. By putting U.S. manufacturing workers into more direct competition with their low-paid counterparts in Mexico, the result is that wages of manufacturing workers in the United States fall.) 

The Post also refuses to acknowledge that the deal has failed to improve Mexico’s growth. In fact, a lead Post editorial in December 2007 told readers that Mexico’s GDP had quadrupled since 1988, which it attributed to the benefits of NAFTA. The actual increase over this 19 year period was 83 percent, which put Mexico near the bottom in growth for Latin American countries.

The Post’s prohibition of honest discussion of Mexico’s economy is apparently continuing. In a piece on Mexico’s elections today, the Post told readers:

“But annual growth during Calderon’s six years has averaged a middling 2 percent.”

This statement gives a whole new meaning to word “middling.” If we turn to the IMF’s data and look at per capita GDP growth in the years 2006-2011, we find that on average Mexico’s per capital GDP shrank by 0.1 percent annually over this period. This is not middling; this performance places Mexico dead last among Latin American countries (several countries in the Caribbean did worse.)

For some reference points, per capita growth in Argentina averaged 5.8 percent, Bolivia 2.8 percent, Brazil 3.1 percent, Ecuador 2.6 percent, and Peru 5.6 percent. There is nothing middling about Mexico’s economic performance over this period; it was bad. 

 

And here’s a graph so that folks can put the Post’s graph showing the rise of Mexico’s per capita income in some context.

per-capita-intl-dollars-07-2012

Source: International Monetary Fund.

See Mexico’s boom?

As noted previously, the Washington Post has a huge stake in saying that NAFTA was a success. As a result, it simply cannot honestly discuss the state of Mexico’s economy in either its news or opinion pages. Today it has a piece that is headlined on the main page of its web site as “Mexico’s middle class begins to boom.” Readers would never know that Mexico has had the worst growth record in all of Latin America over the last decade.

Since the Post seems intent on recycling misleading news stories, I will recycle my comments. The segment below is from July 1 of this year:

The Washington Post Still Can’t Talk Honestly About Mexico’s Economy

The Washington Post is heavily invested in NAFTA. At the time of the debate it abandoned any pretext of being an objective newspaper, allowing both its opinion and news pages to be overwhelmingly dominated by proponents of the agreement. Since its passage the Post has refused to acknowledge that the agreement has had the intended effect in the United States of lowering the wages of manufacturing workers. (This is textbook economics. By putting U.S. manufacturing workers into more direct competition with their low-paid counterparts in Mexico, the result is that wages of manufacturing workers in the United States fall.) 

The Post also refuses to acknowledge that the deal has failed to improve Mexico’s growth. In fact, a lead Post editorial in December 2007 told readers that Mexico’s GDP had quadrupled since 1988, which it attributed to the benefits of NAFTA. The actual increase over this 19 year period was 83 percent, which put Mexico near the bottom in growth for Latin American countries.

The Post’s prohibition of honest discussion of Mexico’s economy is apparently continuing. In a piece on Mexico’s elections today, the Post told readers:

“But annual growth during Calderon’s six years has averaged a middling 2 percent.”

This statement gives a whole new meaning to word “middling.” If we turn to the IMF’s data and look at per capita GDP growth in the years 2006-2011, we find that on average Mexico’s per capital GDP shrank by 0.1 percent annually over this period. This is not middling; this performance places Mexico dead last among Latin American countries (several countries in the Caribbean did worse.)

For some reference points, per capita growth in Argentina averaged 5.8 percent, Bolivia 2.8 percent, Brazil 3.1 percent, Ecuador 2.6 percent, and Peru 5.6 percent. There is nothing middling about Mexico’s economic performance over this period; it was bad. 

 

And here’s a graph so that folks can put the Post’s graph showing the rise of Mexico’s per capita income in some context.

per-capita-intl-dollars-07-2012

Source: International Monetary Fund.

See Mexico’s boom?

It must be very hard to get news at Fox on 15th Street. In the Post’s little primer giving “steps of the euro crisis” step number 3 tells us about the end of cheap credit:

“Following the U.S. credit crisis in 2008, Greece reported a huge deficit increase that suddenly made investors worried about its ability to pay back its loans. High deficits in Portugal, Spain and Ireland caused the price of credit to rise in those countries as well.”

This is an interesting story, but it left out an important part of the picture. Spain and Ireland had been running large budget surpluses prior to the downturn. They were running large deficits in 2008 because they had housing bubbles that collapsed and sent their economies plummeting into recession.

Apparently the Post could not find information about these bubbles or the path of government finances in euro zone countries prior to the downturn. 

It must be very hard to get news at Fox on 15th Street. In the Post’s little primer giving “steps of the euro crisis” step number 3 tells us about the end of cheap credit:

“Following the U.S. credit crisis in 2008, Greece reported a huge deficit increase that suddenly made investors worried about its ability to pay back its loans. High deficits in Portugal, Spain and Ireland caused the price of credit to rise in those countries as well.”

This is an interesting story, but it left out an important part of the picture. Spain and Ireland had been running large budget surpluses prior to the downturn. They were running large deficits in 2008 because they had housing bubbles that collapsed and sent their economies plummeting into recession.

Apparently the Post could not find information about these bubbles or the path of government finances in euro zone countries prior to the downturn. 

Andrew Biggs, an economist at the American Enterprise Institute, is one of the more serious and careful people arguing conservative positions on policy issues. Nonetheless, he strikes out badly in trying to catch me in a contradiction. (Excuse the self-indulgence, consider this a carryover from my birthday boasts.)

Andrew has a blog post where he apparently believes that he has really got me [thanks gov wonk]. I have authored or co-authored several items recently on public pensions in which I argued that it is almost impossible to imagine scenarios in which pensions get returns on their stock holdings that are markedly worse than what they are assuming in their projections (e.g. here and here).

Andrew has my projected returns as averaging 8.9 percent in the current decade and 8.2 percent in the next two decades. (That’s not quite right, but close enough.) He then pulls out his gotcha, a paper from 2000 in which I projected stock returns of 3.4 percent for the first two decades and 3.5 percent for the 2030s. (In a note he points out that he forgot to add 2.8 percent for the inflation rate assumed by the Social Security trustees, whose assumptions provided the basis for my projections.)

So Andrew has me projected 8.9 percent returns and 8.2 percent returns when I was making projections of 6.4 percent and 6.5 percent back in 2000. Should I be wearing a paper bag over my head for the next year in shame?

Perhaps I should, but not because of Andrew’s discovery. In that 2000 paper I wrote:

“It is reasonable to believe … that stocks are temporarily over-valued, and that price-to-earnings ratios will soon fall back to more normal levels [this is the ratio of stock prices to trend earnings]. However, if this is the basis for assuming that stocks will provide their historic rates of return in the future, it would be necessary to include a large decline in stock prices in the projections.”

Andrew probably missed it, but we did in fact have a large decline in stock prices (two actually) between 2000 and the present. That is why I am now confident that we can expect higher rates of return in the future. In other words, I have been 100 percent consistent in my projections of returns, what has changed is the market itself.

I appreciate Andrew’s efforts to remind everyone that I called the stock bubble back in 2000 (actually first in 1997).

Andrew Biggs, an economist at the American Enterprise Institute, is one of the more serious and careful people arguing conservative positions on policy issues. Nonetheless, he strikes out badly in trying to catch me in a contradiction. (Excuse the self-indulgence, consider this a carryover from my birthday boasts.)

Andrew has a blog post where he apparently believes that he has really got me [thanks gov wonk]. I have authored or co-authored several items recently on public pensions in which I argued that it is almost impossible to imagine scenarios in which pensions get returns on their stock holdings that are markedly worse than what they are assuming in their projections (e.g. here and here).

Andrew has my projected returns as averaging 8.9 percent in the current decade and 8.2 percent in the next two decades. (That’s not quite right, but close enough.) He then pulls out his gotcha, a paper from 2000 in which I projected stock returns of 3.4 percent for the first two decades and 3.5 percent for the 2030s. (In a note he points out that he forgot to add 2.8 percent for the inflation rate assumed by the Social Security trustees, whose assumptions provided the basis for my projections.)

So Andrew has me projected 8.9 percent returns and 8.2 percent returns when I was making projections of 6.4 percent and 6.5 percent back in 2000. Should I be wearing a paper bag over my head for the next year in shame?

Perhaps I should, but not because of Andrew’s discovery. In that 2000 paper I wrote:

“It is reasonable to believe … that stocks are temporarily over-valued, and that price-to-earnings ratios will soon fall back to more normal levels [this is the ratio of stock prices to trend earnings]. However, if this is the basis for assuming that stocks will provide their historic rates of return in the future, it would be necessary to include a large decline in stock prices in the projections.”

Andrew probably missed it, but we did in fact have a large decline in stock prices (two actually) between 2000 and the present. That is why I am now confident that we can expect higher rates of return in the future. In other words, I have been 100 percent consistent in my projections of returns, what has changed is the market itself.

I appreciate Andrew’s efforts to remind everyone that I called the stock bubble back in 2000 (actually first in 1997).

Given the failure of the economics profession to see the economic crisis coming or to devise an effective path forward, many people have come to question its competence and/or integrity. Somehow its assessments often seem to favor the rich. For example, economists can be counted on to get really hot under the collar over a 20-30 percent tariff barrier that is designed to temporarily protect manufacturing workers, but don't even notice that patent protection for prescription drugs raises their price by tens of thousands percent. Economists can't even seem to remember that in a system of floating exchange rates, like the one we have, a decline in the value of the dollar is supposed to be the remedy for a trade deficit. The NYT tells us that China's economists are equally incompetent and/or corrupt. It tells us that they are worried that the Chinese are not having enough kids: "Pressure to alter the policy [the one child policy] is building on other fronts as well, as economists say that China’s aging population and dwindling pool of young, cheap labor will be a significant factor in slowing the nation’s economic growth rate." Yes, that sounds like a real problem: "a dwindling pool of cheap labor." Any economist who complains about this is working for the people who want to employ cheap labor, he/she does not give a damn about the economy. Insofar as growth is a measure of anything, it is per capita growth that matters. Why would anyone be happier if the economy grew 20 percent, but population grew 50 percent? This is unambiguously bad for the country as a whole, even if there are some people who might benefit from being able to hire cheaper labor. Economists who are not employed by rich people understand that "cheap labor" means that lots of people are working for little money. This should not be a goal of any honest economist.
Given the failure of the economics profession to see the economic crisis coming or to devise an effective path forward, many people have come to question its competence and/or integrity. Somehow its assessments often seem to favor the rich. For example, economists can be counted on to get really hot under the collar over a 20-30 percent tariff barrier that is designed to temporarily protect manufacturing workers, but don't even notice that patent protection for prescription drugs raises their price by tens of thousands percent. Economists can't even seem to remember that in a system of floating exchange rates, like the one we have, a decline in the value of the dollar is supposed to be the remedy for a trade deficit. The NYT tells us that China's economists are equally incompetent and/or corrupt. It tells us that they are worried that the Chinese are not having enough kids: "Pressure to alter the policy [the one child policy] is building on other fronts as well, as economists say that China’s aging population and dwindling pool of young, cheap labor will be a significant factor in slowing the nation’s economic growth rate." Yes, that sounds like a real problem: "a dwindling pool of cheap labor." Any economist who complains about this is working for the people who want to employ cheap labor, he/she does not give a damn about the economy. Insofar as growth is a measure of anything, it is per capita growth that matters. Why would anyone be happier if the economy grew 20 percent, but population grew 50 percent? This is unambiguously bad for the country as a whole, even if there are some people who might benefit from being able to hire cheaper labor. Economists who are not employed by rich people understand that "cheap labor" means that lots of people are working for little money. This should not be a goal of any honest economist.
Steven Pearlstein, the Washington Post business columnist, often writes insightful pieces on the economy, not today. The thrust of his piece is that we all should be hopeful that a group of incredibly rich CEOs can engineer a coup. While the rest of us are wasting our time worrying about whether Barack Obama or Mitt Romney are sitting in the White House the next four years, Pearlstein tells us (approvingly) that these honchos are scurrying through back rooms in Washington trying to carve out a deficit deal. The plan is that we will get the rich folks' deal regardless of who wins the election. It is difficult to imagine a more contemptuous attitude toward democracy. The deal that this gang (led by Morgan Stanley director Erskine Bowles) is hatching will inevitably include some amount of tax increases and also large budget cuts. At the top of the list, as Pearlstein proudly tells us, are cuts to Social Security and Medicare. At a time when we have seen an unprecedented transfer of income to the top one percent, these deficit warriors are placing a top priority on snatching away a portion of Social Security checks that average $1,200 a month. Yes, the country needs this. The most likely cut to Social Security is a reduction in the annual cost of living adjustment of 0.3 percentage points. While that might sound trivial, the effect accumulates through time. After ten years, a typical check will be about 3 percent lower, after 20 years it will be 6 percent lower, and after 30 years it will be about 9 percent lower. Social Security amounts to 90 percent or more of the income for one-third of seniors. For this group, the proposed cut in benefits would be a considerably larger share of their income that the higher taxes faced by someone earning $300,000 a year as a result of the repeal of the Bush tax cuts on high income earners. The latter is supposed to be a big deal, therefore the proposed cuts to Social Security are also a big deal.
Steven Pearlstein, the Washington Post business columnist, often writes insightful pieces on the economy, not today. The thrust of his piece is that we all should be hopeful that a group of incredibly rich CEOs can engineer a coup. While the rest of us are wasting our time worrying about whether Barack Obama or Mitt Romney are sitting in the White House the next four years, Pearlstein tells us (approvingly) that these honchos are scurrying through back rooms in Washington trying to carve out a deficit deal. The plan is that we will get the rich folks' deal regardless of who wins the election. It is difficult to imagine a more contemptuous attitude toward democracy. The deal that this gang (led by Morgan Stanley director Erskine Bowles) is hatching will inevitably include some amount of tax increases and also large budget cuts. At the top of the list, as Pearlstein proudly tells us, are cuts to Social Security and Medicare. At a time when we have seen an unprecedented transfer of income to the top one percent, these deficit warriors are placing a top priority on snatching away a portion of Social Security checks that average $1,200 a month. Yes, the country needs this. The most likely cut to Social Security is a reduction in the annual cost of living adjustment of 0.3 percentage points. While that might sound trivial, the effect accumulates through time. After ten years, a typical check will be about 3 percent lower, after 20 years it will be 6 percent lower, and after 30 years it will be about 9 percent lower. Social Security amounts to 90 percent or more of the income for one-third of seniors. For this group, the proposed cut in benefits would be a considerably larger share of their income that the higher taxes faced by someone earning $300,000 a year as a result of the repeal of the Bush tax cuts on high income earners. The latter is supposed to be a big deal, therefore the proposed cuts to Social Security are also a big deal.
I guess it's childish name-calling time at the NYT. Hence Bill Keller tells readers that if you ask any "credible economist" you will get Keller's preferred solution to the budget. At the top of the list is "entitlement reforms." For those who don't know, "entitlement reforms" is Washington elite speak for cuts to Social Security and Medicare. They know that these programs are hugely popular, so the Washington elite crew use their little code word "entitlements," since they know that "entitlements" don't have nearly as much support. They also use "reform" since it sounds much nicer than "cuts." Of course the point is to cut Social Security and Medicare; Keller is simply not honest enough to say this to readers. Anyhow, let me just briefly explain why at least one non-credible economist doesn't support the cuts to Social Security and Medicare that former Senator Alan Simpson and Morgan Stanley director Erskine Bowles proposed. (Keller wrongly referred to their plan as a being a plan approved by their commission. This is not true, to be approved as a commission proposal a plan would have required the support of 14 of the 18 members of the commission.) The Bowles-Simpson plan would impose substantial cuts to Social Security benefits that would hit people already getting benefits. It would reduce the annual cost of living adjustment by 0.3 percent. This would lower the benefits that retirees receive by roughly 3 percent after 10 years, 6 percent after 20 years, and  9 percent after 30 years. This will be a serious hit to tens of millions of seniors who rely on Social Security for half or more of their income. Given that the average Social Security check is $1,200 a month, it is a bit hard to accept that these people should be in the center of our gunsights when we turn to deficit reduction.
I guess it's childish name-calling time at the NYT. Hence Bill Keller tells readers that if you ask any "credible economist" you will get Keller's preferred solution to the budget. At the top of the list is "entitlement reforms." For those who don't know, "entitlement reforms" is Washington elite speak for cuts to Social Security and Medicare. They know that these programs are hugely popular, so the Washington elite crew use their little code word "entitlements," since they know that "entitlements" don't have nearly as much support. They also use "reform" since it sounds much nicer than "cuts." Of course the point is to cut Social Security and Medicare; Keller is simply not honest enough to say this to readers. Anyhow, let me just briefly explain why at least one non-credible economist doesn't support the cuts to Social Security and Medicare that former Senator Alan Simpson and Morgan Stanley director Erskine Bowles proposed. (Keller wrongly referred to their plan as a being a plan approved by their commission. This is not true, to be approved as a commission proposal a plan would have required the support of 14 of the 18 members of the commission.) The Bowles-Simpson plan would impose substantial cuts to Social Security benefits that would hit people already getting benefits. It would reduce the annual cost of living adjustment by 0.3 percent. This would lower the benefits that retirees receive by roughly 3 percent after 10 years, 6 percent after 20 years, and  9 percent after 30 years. This will be a serious hit to tens of millions of seniors who rely on Social Security for half or more of their income. Given that the average Social Security check is $1,200 a month, it is a bit hard to accept that these people should be in the center of our gunsights when we turn to deficit reduction.

There are good paying jobs for unskilled people managing pension funds. Floyd Norris reports on how these folks, who get 6-figure salaries, expected to get 8 percent returns even when the price to trend earnings ratio in the stock market exceeded 20 and even 30.

People who know arithmetic could have explained to these managers that this would not be possible. Today many of these pensions are seriously underfunded.

There are good paying jobs for unskilled people managing pension funds. Floyd Norris reports on how these folks, who get 6-figure salaries, expected to get 8 percent returns even when the price to trend earnings ratio in the stock market exceeded 20 and even 30.

People who know arithmetic could have explained to these managers that this would not be possible. Today many of these pensions are seriously underfunded.

Want to search in the archives?

¿Quieres buscar en los archivos?

Click Here Haga clic aquí