Beat the Press

Beat the press por Dean Baker

Beat the Press is Dean Baker's commentary on economic reporting. He is a Senior Economist at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR). To never miss a post, subscribe to a weekly email roundup of Beat the Press. Please also consider supporting the blog on Patreon.

Yep, Catherine Rampell is touting the heroics of the bailout gang in saving us from a second Great Depression in her Washington Post column. She notes the anger directed against this gang on both the left and right and that people suspect their motives. (For those keeping score, the initial trio was Ben Bernanke, who is getting well over $1 million a year in consulting contracts with financial firms, Timothy Geithner, who is likely getting multiple millions as a top exec at a PE company, and Henry Paulson who pocketed hundreds of millions as CEO of Goldman Sachs in the bubble years.)

Anyhow, Rampell never tells us how letting the markets work their magic on the Wall Street bank would have prevented us from passing a really big stimulus in 2009 (or 2010, or 2011 etc.), but I suppose the aluminum foil hat set takes this as an article of faith. Her one piece of evidence is the comparison with Europe, which we are told was meaner to the banks.

I’m not sure that Europe was necessarily meaner to the banks (after all, Deutsche Bank is still in business), but it clearly did have more contractionary fiscal and monetary policy. The European Central Bank raised rates in 2010 to head off the risk of inflation (seriously) and kept Italy, Spain, and Greece in perpetual crisis until it got new leadership at the end of 2011. The European Commission demanded austerity from the crisis countries and even non-crisis countries like France.

The predicted and actual result of these policies was extremely weak growth. It is not clear how the story would be any different if the Europeans had been nicer to the bankers.

Yep, Catherine Rampell is touting the heroics of the bailout gang in saving us from a second Great Depression in her Washington Post column. She notes the anger directed against this gang on both the left and right and that people suspect their motives. (For those keeping score, the initial trio was Ben Bernanke, who is getting well over $1 million a year in consulting contracts with financial firms, Timothy Geithner, who is likely getting multiple millions as a top exec at a PE company, and Henry Paulson who pocketed hundreds of millions as CEO of Goldman Sachs in the bubble years.)

Anyhow, Rampell never tells us how letting the markets work their magic on the Wall Street bank would have prevented us from passing a really big stimulus in 2009 (or 2010, or 2011 etc.), but I suppose the aluminum foil hat set takes this as an article of faith. Her one piece of evidence is the comparison with Europe, which we are told was meaner to the banks.

I’m not sure that Europe was necessarily meaner to the banks (after all, Deutsche Bank is still in business), but it clearly did have more contractionary fiscal and monetary policy. The European Central Bank raised rates in 2010 to head off the risk of inflation (seriously) and kept Italy, Spain, and Greece in perpetual crisis until it got new leadership at the end of 2011. The European Commission demanded austerity from the crisis countries and even non-crisis countries like France.

The predicted and actual result of these policies was extremely weak growth. It is not clear how the story would be any different if the Europeans had been nicer to the bankers.

Samuelson and the Great Recession

Yes, we must thank The Washington Post for running Robert Samuelson. He can always be counted on to get almost everything wrong. He shows this talent yet again in his column on the financial crisis.

He gives us three lessons, with number 1 being the most important, that we could have another great worldwide Great Depression. Yes, this is true, but not because of some mysterious force descending on the world economy.

If we have another Great Depression it will be because governments and central banks refuse to act aggressively to get us out of the Great Depression. Keynes taught us the secret of getting out of a depression. It’s called “spending money.”

The problem is that people with political power, and the news outlets they own (e.g. The Washington Post), often don’t care about tens of millions of people being out of work and losing their homes. (They do care about saving the banks — see Samuelson’s lesson #3.) Therefore, they will rant about budget deficits and government debt, and the burdens we are putting on our kids, even when the most obvious burden we are putting on our kids is keeping their parents from having jobs. Samuelson, of course, is a main promulgator of this line.

We will also hear nonsense about inflation, even as the biggest concern will be an inflation rate that is too low due to the depression. We saw this most clearly with the European Central Bank where outgoing president Jean Claude Trichet patted himself on the back when he retired in 2011. Even though the euro was in crisis at that point (with several countries facing possible defaults) Trichet was proud that he had kept the inflation rate below his 2.0 percent target.

So, Samuelson is correct that we could see another worldwide Great Depression, but not because of anything inherent to the world economy. If we see one, it will be due to an incredibly incompetent and corrupt elite.

By the way, note that no one is acknowledging the role of the housing bubble, and the failure of policy people and economists to see it, in the crisis.

Yes, we must thank The Washington Post for running Robert Samuelson. He can always be counted on to get almost everything wrong. He shows this talent yet again in his column on the financial crisis.

He gives us three lessons, with number 1 being the most important, that we could have another great worldwide Great Depression. Yes, this is true, but not because of some mysterious force descending on the world economy.

If we have another Great Depression it will be because governments and central banks refuse to act aggressively to get us out of the Great Depression. Keynes taught us the secret of getting out of a depression. It’s called “spending money.”

The problem is that people with political power, and the news outlets they own (e.g. The Washington Post), often don’t care about tens of millions of people being out of work and losing their homes. (They do care about saving the banks — see Samuelson’s lesson #3.) Therefore, they will rant about budget deficits and government debt, and the burdens we are putting on our kids, even when the most obvious burden we are putting on our kids is keeping their parents from having jobs. Samuelson, of course, is a main promulgator of this line.

We will also hear nonsense about inflation, even as the biggest concern will be an inflation rate that is too low due to the depression. We saw this most clearly with the European Central Bank where outgoing president Jean Claude Trichet patted himself on the back when he retired in 2011. Even though the euro was in crisis at that point (with several countries facing possible defaults) Trichet was proud that he had kept the inflation rate below his 2.0 percent target.

So, Samuelson is correct that we could see another worldwide Great Depression, but not because of anything inherent to the world economy. If we see one, it will be due to an incredibly incompetent and corrupt elite.

By the way, note that no one is acknowledging the role of the housing bubble, and the failure of policy people and economists to see it, in the crisis.

Four Day Work Weeks Are Sort of Happening

The NYT has a strange piece which treats the idea of a four day work week as a sort of alien concept that perhaps we will see in the 22nd century. It is bizarre because there has been a consistent shortening of the length of work years for well over a century. In Germany, France, and other northern European countries the average work year is between 1400 and 1500 hours. This is due to the fact that workers are now guaranteed 5 to 6 weeks a year of vacation, in addition to paid sick days and paid family leave. The United States has been to a large extent an outlier in that it has seen relatively little reduction in work time over the last four decades.

Presumably, this long trend towards shorter work years will continue. While it may not take the form of a four day work week, workers in many countries have already seen an equivalent reduction in work hours. It is also worth noting that if it really turns out that robots will eliminate many of the jobs that now exist (the productivity data point in the opposite direction) then shorter work years is an obvious way to keep people employed.

The NYT has a strange piece which treats the idea of a four day work week as a sort of alien concept that perhaps we will see in the 22nd century. It is bizarre because there has been a consistent shortening of the length of work years for well over a century. In Germany, France, and other northern European countries the average work year is between 1400 and 1500 hours. This is due to the fact that workers are now guaranteed 5 to 6 weeks a year of vacation, in addition to paid sick days and paid family leave. The United States has been to a large extent an outlier in that it has seen relatively little reduction in work time over the last four decades.

Presumably, this long trend towards shorter work years will continue. While it may not take the form of a four day work week, workers in many countries have already seen an equivalent reduction in work hours. It is also worth noting that if it really turns out that robots will eliminate many of the jobs that now exist (the productivity data point in the opposite direction) then shorter work years is an obvious way to keep people employed.

Stiglitz, Summers, and Secular Stagnation

Last week Joe Stiglitz wrote a piece that included criticisms of the Obama administration for having an inadequate stimulus in response to the Great Recession. Larry Summers, who had been head of Obama’s National Economic Council responded by defending the administration. Stiglitz had a follow-up response to Summers.

Both Stiglitz and Summers are very capable of speaking for themselves so I won’t try to summarize their arguments, but I do want to take issue with one point in Summers’ piece. In his response to Stiglitz, at one point Summers comments:

“He was a signatory to a November 19, 2008 letter also signed by noted progressives James K. Galbraith, Dean Baker, and Larry Mishel calling for a stimulus of $300–$400 billion — less than half of what the Obama administration proposed. So matters were less clear in prospect than in retrospect.”

This is a serious misrepresentation of the letter, which I had helped to draft and circulate. This letter was very clearly referring to a one-year stimulus. It urged leaders in Congress to quickly pass a stimulus:

“The potential severity of the downturn suggests that a boost to demand on the order of 2.0-3.0 percent of GDP ($300-$400 billion) would be appropriate, with the goal being to get this money spent quickly.”

Comparing the sums in a one-year stimulus to the multi-year stimulus request put forward by the Obama administration is comparing apples to oranges.

Furthermore, this letter had been drafted in early October, before we knew the full severity of the downturn following the collapse of the Lehman. At the time of the drafting, we were looking at a job loss of 159,000 reported for September. At the point where the Obama administration was crafting its stimulus package in January of 2009, it was looking at job losses of more than 1.5 million over the prior three months. And the September job loss figure had been revised upward to more than 400,000.

To misrepresent our letter to justify the size of the Obama administration’s stimulus request involves, at the least, an extremely sloppy reading of a one-page document.

Last week Joe Stiglitz wrote a piece that included criticisms of the Obama administration for having an inadequate stimulus in response to the Great Recession. Larry Summers, who had been head of Obama’s National Economic Council responded by defending the administration. Stiglitz had a follow-up response to Summers.

Both Stiglitz and Summers are very capable of speaking for themselves so I won’t try to summarize their arguments, but I do want to take issue with one point in Summers’ piece. In his response to Stiglitz, at one point Summers comments:

“He was a signatory to a November 19, 2008 letter also signed by noted progressives James K. Galbraith, Dean Baker, and Larry Mishel calling for a stimulus of $300–$400 billion — less than half of what the Obama administration proposed. So matters were less clear in prospect than in retrospect.”

This is a serious misrepresentation of the letter, which I had helped to draft and circulate. This letter was very clearly referring to a one-year stimulus. It urged leaders in Congress to quickly pass a stimulus:

“The potential severity of the downturn suggests that a boost to demand on the order of 2.0-3.0 percent of GDP ($300-$400 billion) would be appropriate, with the goal being to get this money spent quickly.”

Comparing the sums in a one-year stimulus to the multi-year stimulus request put forward by the Obama administration is comparing apples to oranges.

Furthermore, this letter had been drafted in early October, before we knew the full severity of the downturn following the collapse of the Lehman. At the time of the drafting, we were looking at a job loss of 159,000 reported for September. At the point where the Obama administration was crafting its stimulus package in January of 2009, it was looking at job losses of more than 1.5 million over the prior three months. And the September job loss figure had been revised upward to more than 400,000.

To misrepresent our letter to justify the size of the Obama administration’s stimulus request involves, at the least, an extremely sloppy reading of a one-page document.

That was one of the items on the list of factors adding to inflationary pressures in China in this NYT article, but it doesn’t seem very plausible. China is on track to import a bit less than $140 billion worth of goods and services from the United States this year. This is less than 1.0 percent of China’s GDP measured at its exchange rate value. (Using a purchasing power parity measure this would be about 0.6 percent.)

Suppose that China’s trade war tariffs add 30 percent to the price of these imports (a very high assumption). This would push up the overall price level by 0.3 percentage points. However, we are continually reminded that much of China’s exports are primarily foreign value-added. Let’s assume that 40 percent of US exports to China end up as value-added in exports either to the US or third countries. This means that the 30 percent rise in price due to tariffs would add 0.18 percentage points to the price level. That is not exactly soaring inflation.

The fact that the yuan has fallen about 6.0 percent against the dollar over the last six months will almost certainly have more impact on China’s inflation rate. The decline in the value of the yuan was not mentioned in the piece.

That was one of the items on the list of factors adding to inflationary pressures in China in this NYT article, but it doesn’t seem very plausible. China is on track to import a bit less than $140 billion worth of goods and services from the United States this year. This is less than 1.0 percent of China’s GDP measured at its exchange rate value. (Using a purchasing power parity measure this would be about 0.6 percent.)

Suppose that China’s trade war tariffs add 30 percent to the price of these imports (a very high assumption). This would push up the overall price level by 0.3 percentage points. However, we are continually reminded that much of China’s exports are primarily foreign value-added. Let’s assume that 40 percent of US exports to China end up as value-added in exports either to the US or third countries. This means that the 30 percent rise in price due to tariffs would add 0.18 percentage points to the price level. That is not exactly soaring inflation.

The fact that the yuan has fallen about 6.0 percent against the dollar over the last six months will almost certainly have more impact on China’s inflation rate. The decline in the value of the yuan was not mentioned in the piece.

Ten years ago we saw the culmination of a period of ungodly economic mismanagement with the collapse of Lehman Brothers and a full-fledged financial crisis. The folks who led us into this disaster rushed to do triage and tend to the most important problem: saving the bankrupt banks.

They also had to cover their tracks. They insisted that the financial crisis was some sort of fluke event — a lot of bad things went wrong simultaneously — and who could have predicted or prevented that? They had a lot of assistance in this coverup because almost all the people who did and wrote about economics at the time also missed the housing bubble and the harm that its inevitable collapse would cause.

The coverup continues to the present, largely because the same people who messed up in the years leading up to the crash are still in positions of authority. They are still the ones writing and talking about economics in major news outlets. So we can expect a lot of “who could have known?” drivel in the weeks ahead.

CEPR will be putting out a paper soon showing once again how the bubble was easy to recognize as was the fact that its collapse would be a disaster. Today I will just share one chart that shows much of the story.

The bubble led to an unprecedented run-up in house prices (with no accompanying rise in real rents), which in turn led to residential construction hitting 6.5 percent of GDP, more than two full percentage points above the long-term average. (But hey, who could have noticed that?)

In addition, the bubble-driven increase in housing wealth led to an unprecedented consumption boom as people spent based on their housing wealth. (This is called the “housing wealth effect” which was very old news by the time I was in graduate school in the 1980s.) This consumption boom could be seen in the plunge in the savings rate which is reported monthly by the Commerce Department. That fell to a low of 2.2 percent in 2005. That compares to an average in the years before the stock wealth effect drove down the savings rate in the 1990s of more than 7.0 percent. It is currently also hovering near 7.0 percent. (FWIW, savings data are subject to large revisions. At the time, the savings rate in 2005 was reported as -0.4 percent [Table 10]).

The question everyone should ask the “who could have known?” crowd is how could you miss the unprecedented run-up in house prices. Even more importantly, how did you miss the extent to which it was driving the economy through the construction and consumption boom? And finally, what on earth did you think would replace more than 5.0 percentage points of GDP worth of lost demand ($1,000 billion in today’s economy) when this housing bubble burst?

Those are pretty simple questions, but you won’t see people asking them in major news outlets. They have too much stake in maintaining the myth that people managing the economy really know what they are doing and the crash and financial crisis were fluke events that could not be foreseen. It ain’t so.

Ten years ago we saw the culmination of a period of ungodly economic mismanagement with the collapse of Lehman Brothers and a full-fledged financial crisis. The folks who led us into this disaster rushed to do triage and tend to the most important problem: saving the bankrupt banks.

They also had to cover their tracks. They insisted that the financial crisis was some sort of fluke event — a lot of bad things went wrong simultaneously — and who could have predicted or prevented that? They had a lot of assistance in this coverup because almost all the people who did and wrote about economics at the time also missed the housing bubble and the harm that its inevitable collapse would cause.

The coverup continues to the present, largely because the same people who messed up in the years leading up to the crash are still in positions of authority. They are still the ones writing and talking about economics in major news outlets. So we can expect a lot of “who could have known?” drivel in the weeks ahead.

CEPR will be putting out a paper soon showing once again how the bubble was easy to recognize as was the fact that its collapse would be a disaster. Today I will just share one chart that shows much of the story.

The bubble led to an unprecedented run-up in house prices (with no accompanying rise in real rents), which in turn led to residential construction hitting 6.5 percent of GDP, more than two full percentage points above the long-term average. (But hey, who could have noticed that?)

In addition, the bubble-driven increase in housing wealth led to an unprecedented consumption boom as people spent based on their housing wealth. (This is called the “housing wealth effect” which was very old news by the time I was in graduate school in the 1980s.) This consumption boom could be seen in the plunge in the savings rate which is reported monthly by the Commerce Department. That fell to a low of 2.2 percent in 2005. That compares to an average in the years before the stock wealth effect drove down the savings rate in the 1990s of more than 7.0 percent. It is currently also hovering near 7.0 percent. (FWIW, savings data are subject to large revisions. At the time, the savings rate in 2005 was reported as -0.4 percent [Table 10]).

The question everyone should ask the “who could have known?” crowd is how could you miss the unprecedented run-up in house prices. Even more importantly, how did you miss the extent to which it was driving the economy through the construction and consumption boom? And finally, what on earth did you think would replace more than 5.0 percentage points of GDP worth of lost demand ($1,000 billion in today’s economy) when this housing bubble burst?

Those are pretty simple questions, but you won’t see people asking them in major news outlets. They have too much stake in maintaining the myth that people managing the economy really know what they are doing and the crash and financial crisis were fluke events that could not be foreseen. It ain’t so.

In an NYT piece assessing the state of the labor market after Friday jobs report, Neil Irwin notes that the employment rate for prime age workers (ages 25 to 54) stood at 79.3 percent in August. That is the same as the 79.3 percent rate in February, indicating that there had been no increase over a six-month period.

However, this may be less compelling as an argument that the labor force is hitting its limits than it initially seems. In August of 2017, the employment rate (EPOP) for prime-age workers stood at 78.4 percent, which also turns out to be the same rate as in February of 2017. In August of 2016, it stood at 77.8 percent, which was also its level in February of 2016. And, in August of 2015, it stood at 77.2 percent. The EPOP for prime-age workers in February of 2015 was also 77.2 percent.

Here’s the picture for the last four years.

Prime Age Employment to Population Ratio

prime age EPOP

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

The data are seasonally adjusted, so the fact that EPOPs have a habit of being the same in August as February can’t be blamed on seasonal factors. It is simply a weird coincidence. But, this should be a warning against putting much stock in the view that the economy is hitting its limits based on the August employment data.

As the good book says, the household data are highly erratic. When you see a weird movement in one month’s data, it is most likely a fluke. You should want to see two or three months before believing it is actually telling us something about the world.

In an NYT piece assessing the state of the labor market after Friday jobs report, Neil Irwin notes that the employment rate for prime age workers (ages 25 to 54) stood at 79.3 percent in August. That is the same as the 79.3 percent rate in February, indicating that there had been no increase over a six-month period.

However, this may be less compelling as an argument that the labor force is hitting its limits than it initially seems. In August of 2017, the employment rate (EPOP) for prime-age workers stood at 78.4 percent, which also turns out to be the same rate as in February of 2017. In August of 2016, it stood at 77.8 percent, which was also its level in February of 2016. And, in August of 2015, it stood at 77.2 percent. The EPOP for prime-age workers in February of 2015 was also 77.2 percent.

Here’s the picture for the last four years.

Prime Age Employment to Population Ratio

prime age EPOP

Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics

The data are seasonally adjusted, so the fact that EPOPs have a habit of being the same in August as February can’t be blamed on seasonal factors. It is simply a weird coincidence. But, this should be a warning against putting much stock in the view that the economy is hitting its limits based on the August employment data.

As the good book says, the household data are highly erratic. When you see a weird movement in one month’s data, it is most likely a fluke. You should want to see two or three months before believing it is actually telling us something about the world.

The New York Times had a piece on how education secretary Betty DeVos is trying to block state efforts to prevent abusive practices by student loan servicers after she had weakened federal protections. Her argument is the same one that the federal government used to weaken state rules on mortgage lending practices during the housing bubble years — that federal law preempts state law.

I’ll leave it to the lawyers to decide the legal question here, but the economic one is straightforward. If servicers can make money from abusive practices (e.g. harassing phone calls, illegal threats, and charging arbitrary fees), they will. That is what we expect in a free market economy, businesses try to maximize profit.

While the piece treats this as a consumer protection issue, which it is, it is also one of economic efficiency. If it is possible to make lots of money by ripping off students in servicing their loans, then businesses will devote resources to ripping off students rather than something productive.

Think of it like making stealing cars legal. If people could make lots of money by stealing cars, many will quit their day job and spend their time stealing other people’s cars.

We should also understand the issue of government-issued or government-insured student loans for tuition at for-profit universities the same way. Many of these universities provide little in the way of education and do not give students a marketable skill. As a result, the default rate on loans at many of these schools is often over 40 or 50 percent.

For these for-profit colleges, the students are simply intermediaries to access to government money. They allow students to make tuition payments which they could not possibly do otherwise. The students basically get nothing for their money, but in a world where the government requires no accountability from the schools, this doesn’t matter.

It seems that for Betty DeVos, the point of the student loan program is to make the people who own these for-profit colleges richer with taxpayer money. In this respect, it is probably worth noting that she made the dean of DeVry University, one of the biggest for-profits with a very high default rate, head of the student loan fraud division at the Education Department.

The New York Times had a piece on how education secretary Betty DeVos is trying to block state efforts to prevent abusive practices by student loan servicers after she had weakened federal protections. Her argument is the same one that the federal government used to weaken state rules on mortgage lending practices during the housing bubble years — that federal law preempts state law.

I’ll leave it to the lawyers to decide the legal question here, but the economic one is straightforward. If servicers can make money from abusive practices (e.g. harassing phone calls, illegal threats, and charging arbitrary fees), they will. That is what we expect in a free market economy, businesses try to maximize profit.

While the piece treats this as a consumer protection issue, which it is, it is also one of economic efficiency. If it is possible to make lots of money by ripping off students in servicing their loans, then businesses will devote resources to ripping off students rather than something productive.

Think of it like making stealing cars legal. If people could make lots of money by stealing cars, many will quit their day job and spend their time stealing other people’s cars.

We should also understand the issue of government-issued or government-insured student loans for tuition at for-profit universities the same way. Many of these universities provide little in the way of education and do not give students a marketable skill. As a result, the default rate on loans at many of these schools is often over 40 or 50 percent.

For these for-profit colleges, the students are simply intermediaries to access to government money. They allow students to make tuition payments which they could not possibly do otherwise. The students basically get nothing for their money, but in a world where the government requires no accountability from the schools, this doesn’t matter.

It seems that for Betty DeVos, the point of the student loan program is to make the people who own these for-profit colleges richer with taxpayer money. In this respect, it is probably worth noting that she made the dean of DeVry University, one of the biggest for-profits with a very high default rate, head of the student loan fraud division at the Education Department.

NYT readers were no doubt disturbed to see a column in which former Fed Reserve Board chair Ben Bernanke, Obama Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner, and Bush Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson patted themselves on the back for their performance in the financial crisis. First, as they acknowledge in the piece, all three completely failed to see the crisis coming. During the years when house prices were getting way out of line with both their long-term trend and rents, Bernanke was a Fed governor, then head of the Council of Economic Advisers, and then Fed chair. He openly dismissed the idea that the run-up in house prices could pose any threat to the economy. Henry Paulson was at Goldman Sachs until he became Treasury Secretary in the middle of 2006. As the bank's CEO, he was personally profiting from the bubble as the bank played a central role in securitizing mortgage-backed securities. Timothy Geithner was president of the New York Fed, where he was paid over $400,000 a year to make sure that the Wall Street banks were not taking on excessive risk. It is bad enough that these three didn't see the crisis coming, but they still seem utterly clueless. They tell readers: "Productivity growth was slowing, wages were stagnating, and the share of Americans who were working was shrinking. That put pressure on family incomes even as inequality rose and upward social mobility declined. The desire to maintain relative living standards no doubt contributed to a surge in household borrowing before the crisis." Actually, productivity growth didn't begin to slow until 2006, as the bubble was hitting its peak. Growth was quite strong from 2000 to 2005, which means the cause of wage stagnation in those years must lie elsewhere. (If they had access to government trade data they might think the explosion of the trade deficit to 6.0 percent of GDP played a role.) The surge in borrowing clearly preceded the productivity slowdown as could be seen from the plunge in savings rates or reading the papers celebrating people pulling equity out of their homes by some guy named Alan Greenspan.
NYT readers were no doubt disturbed to see a column in which former Fed Reserve Board chair Ben Bernanke, Obama Treasury Secretary Timothy Geithner, and Bush Treasury Secretary Henry Paulson patted themselves on the back for their performance in the financial crisis. First, as they acknowledge in the piece, all three completely failed to see the crisis coming. During the years when house prices were getting way out of line with both their long-term trend and rents, Bernanke was a Fed governor, then head of the Council of Economic Advisers, and then Fed chair. He openly dismissed the idea that the run-up in house prices could pose any threat to the economy. Henry Paulson was at Goldman Sachs until he became Treasury Secretary in the middle of 2006. As the bank's CEO, he was personally profiting from the bubble as the bank played a central role in securitizing mortgage-backed securities. Timothy Geithner was president of the New York Fed, where he was paid over $400,000 a year to make sure that the Wall Street banks were not taking on excessive risk. It is bad enough that these three didn't see the crisis coming, but they still seem utterly clueless. They tell readers: "Productivity growth was slowing, wages were stagnating, and the share of Americans who were working was shrinking. That put pressure on family incomes even as inequality rose and upward social mobility declined. The desire to maintain relative living standards no doubt contributed to a surge in household borrowing before the crisis." Actually, productivity growth didn't begin to slow until 2006, as the bubble was hitting its peak. Growth was quite strong from 2000 to 2005, which means the cause of wage stagnation in those years must lie elsewhere. (If they had access to government trade data they might think the explosion of the trade deficit to 6.0 percent of GDP played a role.) The surge in borrowing clearly preceded the productivity slowdown as could be seen from the plunge in savings rates or reading the papers celebrating people pulling equity out of their homes by some guy named Alan Greenspan.

Affordable Care Act

Medicare for All Battles

(This post originally appeared on my Patreon page.) The Fact Check gang has been having a field day going after Bernie Sanders, Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez and other proponents of Medicare for All. The latest battle is over a study produced by the right-wing Mercatus which showed that a government-run health care program could reduce national health expenditures by $2 trillion over the course of a decade (roughly 0.8 percent of GDP). Sanders and Ocasio-Cortez seized on this projection of savings coming out of a right-wing think tank as support for the greater efficiency of a universal Medicare program. Of course, this was not the point that the Mercatus folks intended people to get from their study. They highlighted the fact that their projections showed Medicare for All increasing costs to the federal government by $32.6 trillion over the first ten years of operation, with the amount equal to 10.7 percent of GDP in 2022 and rising to 12.7 percent of GDP in 2031. The fact check crew definitely went overboard in attacking Sanders and Ocasio-Cortez for misrepresenting the study. One scenario in the study did, in fact, show that Medicare for All would reduce national health care expenditures by $2 trillion over the decade.
(This post originally appeared on my Patreon page.) The Fact Check gang has been having a field day going after Bernie Sanders, Alexandria Ocasio-Cortez and other proponents of Medicare for All. The latest battle is over a study produced by the right-wing Mercatus which showed that a government-run health care program could reduce national health expenditures by $2 trillion over the course of a decade (roughly 0.8 percent of GDP). Sanders and Ocasio-Cortez seized on this projection of savings coming out of a right-wing think tank as support for the greater efficiency of a universal Medicare program. Of course, this was not the point that the Mercatus folks intended people to get from their study. They highlighted the fact that their projections showed Medicare for All increasing costs to the federal government by $32.6 trillion over the first ten years of operation, with the amount equal to 10.7 percent of GDP in 2022 and rising to 12.7 percent of GDP in 2031. The fact check crew definitely went overboard in attacking Sanders and Ocasio-Cortez for misrepresenting the study. One scenario in the study did, in fact, show that Medicare for All would reduce national health care expenditures by $2 trillion over the decade.

Want to search in the archives?

¿Quieres buscar en los archivos?

Click Here Haga clic aquí