Beat the Press

Beat the press por Dean Baker

Beat the Press is Dean Baker's commentary on economic reporting. He is a Senior Economist at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR). To never miss a post, subscribe to a weekly email roundup of Beat the Press. Please also consider supporting the blog on Patreon.

The medical device industry is pushing hard to repeal a tax imposed as part of the Affordable Care Act (ACA). The NYT had an article on its massive bipartisan lobbying effort. While the piece notes in passing that, “the White House argues that demand for new devices will offset the economic impact of the tax,” the piece doesn’t explain what this means.

The marginal cost of producing most medical devices is very low relative to their price. The companies are in effect collecting a big premium because of their patent monopolies. The ACA meant that they would sell many more devices and therefore collect a much higher dividend from their patents, even though the amount spent on research had not changed.

To see the logic here, imagine that it costs a medical company nothing to produce a scanner that it will sell for $1 million apiece. (Again, the high price is allowing it to recover development costs.) Before the ACA it would have expected to sell 1000 scanners, netting it $1 billion. After the ACA the company can expect to sell 1100 scanners, netting it $1.1 billion.

The tax is intended to recoup this additional $100 million. While the tax hit will not be exactly offsetting to the increased profit to the industry in every case, on average this will be the case. In other words, the White House is not making a bizarre argument, they are presenting the facts. The industry is trying to pocket extra profits as a dividend from the ACA and does not want the government to tax back part, or all, of this dividend.

The medical device industry is pushing hard to repeal a tax imposed as part of the Affordable Care Act (ACA). The NYT had an article on its massive bipartisan lobbying effort. While the piece notes in passing that, “the White House argues that demand for new devices will offset the economic impact of the tax,” the piece doesn’t explain what this means.

The marginal cost of producing most medical devices is very low relative to their price. The companies are in effect collecting a big premium because of their patent monopolies. The ACA meant that they would sell many more devices and therefore collect a much higher dividend from their patents, even though the amount spent on research had not changed.

To see the logic here, imagine that it costs a medical company nothing to produce a scanner that it will sell for $1 million apiece. (Again, the high price is allowing it to recover development costs.) Before the ACA it would have expected to sell 1000 scanners, netting it $1 billion. After the ACA the company can expect to sell 1100 scanners, netting it $1.1 billion.

The tax is intended to recoup this additional $100 million. While the tax hit will not be exactly offsetting to the increased profit to the industry in every case, on average this will be the case. In other words, the White House is not making a bizarre argument, they are presenting the facts. The industry is trying to pocket extra profits as a dividend from the ACA and does not want the government to tax back part, or all, of this dividend.

The Washington Post has a piece puzzling over the fact that:

“Builders started work on 27.7 percent more homes in February than they did a year earlier. Yet the number of construction jobs in the United States was only 2.9 percent higher, year-over-year.”

The Post turned to analysts at Goldman Sachs who concluded that the answer was labor hoarding. They make a case that firms are changing the length of the workweek to meet the increased demand for labor rather than adding more workers. This one doesn’t fly.

First, residential construction is a comparatively low-paying sector with casual labor relations. This is not General Motors with union contracts that make layoffs difficult. In other words, it is not a sector where we would expect to see a lot of labor hoarding.

The data on hours shown in the piece also do not support the labor hoarding story. While the average workweek has increased by roughly 3 hours since the trough of the downturn in 2009, it is up by only about 0.5 hours since 2011, which means that it would be equivalent to an increase in employment of less than 2 percent. That will not fill much of the gap identified in the piece.

So, what’s the real story? First, total construction is up by much less than residential construction. The Commerce Department reported that total nominal construction was 7.1 percent higher in January of 2013 than January of 2012. In real terms this would be a rise of around 5.0 percent, not too different from the increase in employment.

The other big issue is that many of the workers employed in residential construction are undocumented and may not show up in the payroll data. In fact, there was a sharp decline in residential construction in 2006 and 2007 even as employment in construction was still growing. From its peak in 2005 to the end of 2007 housing starts fell by almost 40 percent, while construction employment was little changed. Given this history, there is no reason to expect a big upturn in employment in response to the relatively small rise in starts that we have seen in the last year.

Click for larger version

housing-houst-nppcon-2013

The Washington Post has a piece puzzling over the fact that:

“Builders started work on 27.7 percent more homes in February than they did a year earlier. Yet the number of construction jobs in the United States was only 2.9 percent higher, year-over-year.”

The Post turned to analysts at Goldman Sachs who concluded that the answer was labor hoarding. They make a case that firms are changing the length of the workweek to meet the increased demand for labor rather than adding more workers. This one doesn’t fly.

First, residential construction is a comparatively low-paying sector with casual labor relations. This is not General Motors with union contracts that make layoffs difficult. In other words, it is not a sector where we would expect to see a lot of labor hoarding.

The data on hours shown in the piece also do not support the labor hoarding story. While the average workweek has increased by roughly 3 hours since the trough of the downturn in 2009, it is up by only about 0.5 hours since 2011, which means that it would be equivalent to an increase in employment of less than 2 percent. That will not fill much of the gap identified in the piece.

So, what’s the real story? First, total construction is up by much less than residential construction. The Commerce Department reported that total nominal construction was 7.1 percent higher in January of 2013 than January of 2012. In real terms this would be a rise of around 5.0 percent, not too different from the increase in employment.

The other big issue is that many of the workers employed in residential construction are undocumented and may not show up in the payroll data. In fact, there was a sharp decline in residential construction in 2006 and 2007 even as employment in construction was still growing. From its peak in 2005 to the end of 2007 housing starts fell by almost 40 percent, while construction employment was little changed. Given this history, there is no reason to expect a big upturn in employment in response to the relatively small rise in starts that we have seen in the last year.

Click for larger version

housing-houst-nppcon-2013

A Morning Edition piece on the housing market blamed difficulties in the housing market in part on people being unable to get mortgages because of inaccurate appraisals. In fact, this should not on average reduce sales. While some sales will be prevented by an appraisal that wrongly comes in too low, some sales will go through that should not because an inaccurate appraisal comes in too high. Unless there is some reason there is a low side bias to the appraisals, inaccuracy by itself should not affect total sales.

A Morning Edition piece on the housing market blamed difficulties in the housing market in part on people being unable to get mortgages because of inaccurate appraisals. In fact, this should not on average reduce sales. While some sales will be prevented by an appraisal that wrongly comes in too low, some sales will go through that should not because an inaccurate appraisal comes in too high. Unless there is some reason there is a low side bias to the appraisals, inaccuracy by itself should not affect total sales.

David Brooks has trouble with issues of logic and arithmetic as he frequently demonstrates in his column. His criticisms of the Congressional Progressive Caucus (CPC) budget suffer badly from this problem. The piece begins by telling readers that the CPC has broken with past liberalism by seeing the government, rather than the private sector, as the engine of growth. His basis for this argument is that the CPC proposes a large program of public investment to restore the economy to full employment. Brooks distinguishes this spending from prior efforts at stimulus: "liberals have always believed in Keynesian countercyclical deficit spending. But that was borrowing to brake against a downturn when certain conditions prevail: when the economy is shrinking; when debt levels are low; when there are plenty of shovel-ready projects waiting to be enacted; when there is a large and growing gap between the economy’s current output and what it is capable of producing. "Today, House progressives are calling for a huge increase in government taxing and spending when none of those conditions apply. Today, progressives are calling on government to be the growth engine in all circumstances. In this phase of the recovery, just as the economy is finally beginning to take off..." Let's see, Keynes advocated large amounts of spending when the debt to GDP ratio in the United Kingdom was well over 100 percent. (FWIW, our interest to GDP ratio is extraordinarily low.) He also advocated this spending when the economy was not shrinking, it was just stagnant or growing slowly at a time when there was mass unemployment and the economy was far below its potential. Maybe Brooks doesn't consider Keynes a Keynesian.
David Brooks has trouble with issues of logic and arithmetic as he frequently demonstrates in his column. His criticisms of the Congressional Progressive Caucus (CPC) budget suffer badly from this problem. The piece begins by telling readers that the CPC has broken with past liberalism by seeing the government, rather than the private sector, as the engine of growth. His basis for this argument is that the CPC proposes a large program of public investment to restore the economy to full employment. Brooks distinguishes this spending from prior efforts at stimulus: "liberals have always believed in Keynesian countercyclical deficit spending. But that was borrowing to brake against a downturn when certain conditions prevail: when the economy is shrinking; when debt levels are low; when there are plenty of shovel-ready projects waiting to be enacted; when there is a large and growing gap between the economy’s current output and what it is capable of producing. "Today, House progressives are calling for a huge increase in government taxing and spending when none of those conditions apply. Today, progressives are calling on government to be the growth engine in all circumstances. In this phase of the recovery, just as the economy is finally beginning to take off..." Let's see, Keynes advocated large amounts of spending when the debt to GDP ratio in the United Kingdom was well over 100 percent. (FWIW, our interest to GDP ratio is extraordinarily low.) He also advocated this spending when the economy was not shrinking, it was just stagnant or growing slowly at a time when there was mass unemployment and the economy was far below its potential. Maybe Brooks doesn't consider Keynes a Keynesian.

Business news stories and op-ed columns are filled with comments about the economy picking up steam. The case is less obvious to those of us who look at the data. February’s reported job growth of 236,000 wasn’t bad, but it was not quite as good as the 271,000 job gain reported last February or the 311,000 new jobs reported for January of 2012. It pays to step back and look at the big picture. Most forecasts show growth under 2.0 percent in 2012. We have little reason at this point to assume that these forecasts are overly pessimistic.

Business news stories and op-ed columns are filled with comments about the economy picking up steam. The case is less obvious to those of us who look at the data. February’s reported job growth of 236,000 wasn’t bad, but it was not quite as good as the 271,000 job gain reported last February or the 311,000 new jobs reported for January of 2012. It pays to step back and look at the big picture. Most forecasts show growth under 2.0 percent in 2012. We have little reason at this point to assume that these forecasts are overly pessimistic.

Okay, that's not exactly what Robert Samuelson said, but pretty close. He actually told readers: "What frustrates constructive debate is muddled public opinion." I just thought I would make a small change in the interest of accuracy. Samuelson is very upset because almost no one, Democrat, Republican, or independent wants to go along with his crusade to cut Social Security and Medicare. He tells readers with disgust: "In a Pew poll, 87 percent of respondents favored present or greater Social Security spending; only 10 percent backed cuts." He then demands that President Obama rise to the occasion and insist that people accept lower benefits. President Obama's time can probably be more productively spent teaching economics and arithmetic to people who write on budget issues in major news outlets. Most of the main assertions in Samuelson's piece are misleading or just flat out wrong. First, the budget is only constrained at the moment by superstition. There is no obstacle to the government borrowing more money to meet needs and put people back to work. We are not spending more money because we have superstitious people with large amounts of power who are making claims about the dangers of deficits that they cannot support with evidence. Rather than lecturing seniors, who have a median income of $20,000, on the need for lower Social Security and Medicare benefits, Obama could try to confront the people spreading superstitions about deficits. Samuelson's complaint about the size of spending on the elderly is also highly misleading. He complains: "In fiscal 2012, Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid and civil service and military retirement cost $1.7 trillion, about half the budget."
Okay, that's not exactly what Robert Samuelson said, but pretty close. He actually told readers: "What frustrates constructive debate is muddled public opinion." I just thought I would make a small change in the interest of accuracy. Samuelson is very upset because almost no one, Democrat, Republican, or independent wants to go along with his crusade to cut Social Security and Medicare. He tells readers with disgust: "In a Pew poll, 87 percent of respondents favored present or greater Social Security spending; only 10 percent backed cuts." He then demands that President Obama rise to the occasion and insist that people accept lower benefits. President Obama's time can probably be more productively spent teaching economics and arithmetic to people who write on budget issues in major news outlets. Most of the main assertions in Samuelson's piece are misleading or just flat out wrong. First, the budget is only constrained at the moment by superstition. There is no obstacle to the government borrowing more money to meet needs and put people back to work. We are not spending more money because we have superstitious people with large amounts of power who are making claims about the dangers of deficits that they cannot support with evidence. Rather than lecturing seniors, who have a median income of $20,000, on the need for lower Social Security and Medicare benefits, Obama could try to confront the people spreading superstitions about deficits. Samuelson's complaint about the size of spending on the elderly is also highly misleading. He complains: "In fiscal 2012, Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid and civil service and military retirement cost $1.7 trillion, about half the budget."
The Washington Post had a major column by Steve Pearlstein on the front page of its Outlook section headlined, "Is Capitalism Moral?" The piece notes the sharp upward redistribution of income over the last three decades and asks whether we should just being willing to accept market outcomes. Of course this question is absurd on its face. The upward redistribution of the last three decades was the result of deliberate government policies designed to redistribute income upward; it was not the natural workings of the market. For example, trade policy was quite explicitly intended to place segments of the U.S. workforce in direct competition with low paid workers in Mexico, China and other developing countries. The predicted and actual result of this policy has been to push down the wages the bottom 50-70 percent of the workforce to the benefit of those at the top. This was hardly the free market. We could have adopted trade policies that were designed to put doctors, lawyers and other highly paid professionals in direct competition with their much lower paid counterparts in the developing world. If we had done this, doctors in the U.S. might be earning closer to $100,000 a year rather than the current average of more than $250,000 annually. This would transfer more than $100 billion annually to the rest of the country in the form of lower health care costs. The government also strengthened and lengthened the periods of monopoly protection provided by both patents and copyrights. This has hugely increased the amount of rents being paid to high-end earners, the pharmaceutical industry and the entertainment industry at the expense of everyone else.
The Washington Post had a major column by Steve Pearlstein on the front page of its Outlook section headlined, "Is Capitalism Moral?" The piece notes the sharp upward redistribution of income over the last three decades and asks whether we should just being willing to accept market outcomes. Of course this question is absurd on its face. The upward redistribution of the last three decades was the result of deliberate government policies designed to redistribute income upward; it was not the natural workings of the market. For example, trade policy was quite explicitly intended to place segments of the U.S. workforce in direct competition with low paid workers in Mexico, China and other developing countries. The predicted and actual result of this policy has been to push down the wages the bottom 50-70 percent of the workforce to the benefit of those at the top. This was hardly the free market. We could have adopted trade policies that were designed to put doctors, lawyers and other highly paid professionals in direct competition with their much lower paid counterparts in the developing world. If we had done this, doctors in the U.S. might be earning closer to $100,000 a year rather than the current average of more than $250,000 annually. This would transfer more than $100 billion annually to the rest of the country in the form of lower health care costs. The government also strengthened and lengthened the periods of monopoly protection provided by both patents and copyrights. This has hugely increased the amount of rents being paid to high-end earners, the pharmaceutical industry and the entertainment industry at the expense of everyone else.

That could have been the title of a Washington Post editorial that criticizes the budget produced by Senate Democrats because it doesn’t address the possibility that we will have a rising debt to GDP ratio in 2023. After all, millions of lives are being ruined by the high unemployment that resulted from the ineptitude of the people that the Post views as experts on the economy. The Post is completely unconcerned about this crisis. Instead it is very upset that Senate Democrats are not worried about projections for 2023 and beyond of a rising debt to GDP ratio.

It is worth remembering that back in 2000 there was a major debate in Washington over the date at which the federal government would pay off the national debt. The Washington Post was a major actor in this debate.

Btw, the Post has this classic included in its list of ways to deal with Social Security:

“a more realistic inflation adjustment.”

Of course the Washington Post does not have a clue as to whether its preferred price index better reflects the rate of inflation seen by Social Security beneficiaries. All it knows is that it will show a lower rate of inflation and therefore cut benefits. You’ve gotta love these folks.

That could have been the title of a Washington Post editorial that criticizes the budget produced by Senate Democrats because it doesn’t address the possibility that we will have a rising debt to GDP ratio in 2023. After all, millions of lives are being ruined by the high unemployment that resulted from the ineptitude of the people that the Post views as experts on the economy. The Post is completely unconcerned about this crisis. Instead it is very upset that Senate Democrats are not worried about projections for 2023 and beyond of a rising debt to GDP ratio.

It is worth remembering that back in 2000 there was a major debate in Washington over the date at which the federal government would pay off the national debt. The Washington Post was a major actor in this debate.

Btw, the Post has this classic included in its list of ways to deal with Social Security:

“a more realistic inflation adjustment.”

Of course the Washington Post does not have a clue as to whether its preferred price index better reflects the rate of inflation seen by Social Security beneficiaries. All it knows is that it will show a lower rate of inflation and therefore cut benefits. You’ve gotta love these folks.

The NYT had an interesting piece on new research from the Urban Institute showing that young people are faring very poorly in the economy. In presenting the list of problems facing young workers it included the collapse of the housing bubble.

In fact this was great news for young people in terms of their ability to buy homes. (The impact on the economy was of course devastating.) Since the overwhelming majority of young workers were not homeowners prior to the collapse of the bubble, the drop in prices means that they can buy a home for close to 30 percent less than what they would have paid 6 or 7 years ago. This is effectively a transfer of tens of thousands of dollars from older generations to the young. This is very good news for them.

The NYT had an interesting piece on new research from the Urban Institute showing that young people are faring very poorly in the economy. In presenting the list of problems facing young workers it included the collapse of the housing bubble.

In fact this was great news for young people in terms of their ability to buy homes. (The impact on the economy was of course devastating.) Since the overwhelming majority of young workers were not homeowners prior to the collapse of the bubble, the drop in prices means that they can buy a home for close to 30 percent less than what they would have paid 6 or 7 years ago. This is effectively a transfer of tens of thousands of dollars from older generations to the young. This is very good news for them.

Given the disastrous failure of the economics profession to warn of the housing bubble, it is amazing that the country has not rounded up the lot of us (I'll go too) and chased us out of the country. Unfortunately, we still have a profession continuing to use its authority to spread confusion rather than enlightenment.  Thomas Edsall and his readers are the victims today. In an interesting discussion of trends in poverty, Edsall includes a reference to work by Bruce Meyer and James Sullivan that shows poverty among the elderly has fallen to just 3.2 percent using a consumption based measure of poverty. There are many issues that can be raised about this analysis, as my colleague Shawn Fremstad has pointed out. However perhaps the most fundamental point for purposes of Edsall's analysis, which explicitly compares poverty rates among the young and the old, is the fact that Meyer and Sullivan: "report results using an adjusted CPIU-RS that subtracts 0.8 percentage points from the growth in the CPI-U-RS index each year (p 17)." Okay, if the meaning of this line is not immediately clear, Meyer and Sullivan are assuming that actual rate of annual inflation is 0.8 percentage points less than official data show. This claim is debatable, but its implications are not. If we have been overstating inflation by 0.8 percentage point each year, then we have been understating real income growth by 0.8 percentage points. This claim lies at the center of Meyer and Sullivan's claim that poverty has fallen sharply. Their adjustment would mean that income has risen by roughly 8 percent more over the last decade than official data show and 16 percent more over the last two decades. (I'm ignoring compounding to keep this simple.) This additional rise in income (or consumption) gets a lot of people over the poverty line. The Meyer and Sullivan assumption has another important implication which they do not discuss in this paper and apparently did not discuss in their conversations with Mr. Edsall. If income is growing more rapidly than the official data indicate then people were much poorer in the recent past than official data indicate.
Given the disastrous failure of the economics profession to warn of the housing bubble, it is amazing that the country has not rounded up the lot of us (I'll go too) and chased us out of the country. Unfortunately, we still have a profession continuing to use its authority to spread confusion rather than enlightenment.  Thomas Edsall and his readers are the victims today. In an interesting discussion of trends in poverty, Edsall includes a reference to work by Bruce Meyer and James Sullivan that shows poverty among the elderly has fallen to just 3.2 percent using a consumption based measure of poverty. There are many issues that can be raised about this analysis, as my colleague Shawn Fremstad has pointed out. However perhaps the most fundamental point for purposes of Edsall's analysis, which explicitly compares poverty rates among the young and the old, is the fact that Meyer and Sullivan: "report results using an adjusted CPIU-RS that subtracts 0.8 percentage points from the growth in the CPI-U-RS index each year (p 17)." Okay, if the meaning of this line is not immediately clear, Meyer and Sullivan are assuming that actual rate of annual inflation is 0.8 percentage points less than official data show. This claim is debatable, but its implications are not. If we have been overstating inflation by 0.8 percentage point each year, then we have been understating real income growth by 0.8 percentage points. This claim lies at the center of Meyer and Sullivan's claim that poverty has fallen sharply. Their adjustment would mean that income has risen by roughly 8 percent more over the last decade than official data show and 16 percent more over the last two decades. (I'm ignoring compounding to keep this simple.) This additional rise in income (or consumption) gets a lot of people over the poverty line. The Meyer and Sullivan assumption has another important implication which they do not discuss in this paper and apparently did not discuss in their conversations with Mr. Edsall. If income is growing more rapidly than the official data indicate then people were much poorer in the recent past than official data indicate.

Want to search in the archives?

¿Quieres buscar en los archivos?

Click Here Haga clic aquí