Beat the Press

Beat the press por Dean Baker

Beat the Press is Dean Baker's commentary on economic reporting. He is a Senior Economist at the Center for Economic and Policy Research (CEPR). To never miss a post, subscribe to a weekly email roundup of Beat the Press. Please also consider supporting the blog on Patreon.

It must be very hard to get news at Fox on 15th Street. In the Post’s little primer giving “steps of the euro crisis” step number 3 tells us about the end of cheap credit:

“Following the U.S. credit crisis in 2008, Greece reported a huge deficit increase that suddenly made investors worried about its ability to pay back its loans. High deficits in Portugal, Spain and Ireland caused the price of credit to rise in those countries as well.”

This is an interesting story, but it left out an important part of the picture. Spain and Ireland had been running large budget surpluses prior to the downturn. They were running large deficits in 2008 because they had housing bubbles that collapsed and sent their economies plummeting into recession.

Apparently the Post could not find information about these bubbles or the path of government finances in euro zone countries prior to the downturn. 

It must be very hard to get news at Fox on 15th Street. In the Post’s little primer giving “steps of the euro crisis” step number 3 tells us about the end of cheap credit:

“Following the U.S. credit crisis in 2008, Greece reported a huge deficit increase that suddenly made investors worried about its ability to pay back its loans. High deficits in Portugal, Spain and Ireland caused the price of credit to rise in those countries as well.”

This is an interesting story, but it left out an important part of the picture. Spain and Ireland had been running large budget surpluses prior to the downturn. They were running large deficits in 2008 because they had housing bubbles that collapsed and sent their economies plummeting into recession.

Apparently the Post could not find information about these bubbles or the path of government finances in euro zone countries prior to the downturn. 

Andrew Biggs, an economist at the American Enterprise Institute, is one of the more serious and careful people arguing conservative positions on policy issues. Nonetheless, he strikes out badly in trying to catch me in a contradiction. (Excuse the self-indulgence, consider this a carryover from my birthday boasts.)

Andrew has a blog post where he apparently believes that he has really got me [thanks gov wonk]. I have authored or co-authored several items recently on public pensions in which I argued that it is almost impossible to imagine scenarios in which pensions get returns on their stock holdings that are markedly worse than what they are assuming in their projections (e.g. here and here).

Andrew has my projected returns as averaging 8.9 percent in the current decade and 8.2 percent in the next two decades. (That’s not quite right, but close enough.) He then pulls out his gotcha, a paper from 2000 in which I projected stock returns of 3.4 percent for the first two decades and 3.5 percent for the 2030s. (In a note he points out that he forgot to add 2.8 percent for the inflation rate assumed by the Social Security trustees, whose assumptions provided the basis for my projections.)

So Andrew has me projected 8.9 percent returns and 8.2 percent returns when I was making projections of 6.4 percent and 6.5 percent back in 2000. Should I be wearing a paper bag over my head for the next year in shame?

Perhaps I should, but not because of Andrew’s discovery. In that 2000 paper I wrote:

“It is reasonable to believe … that stocks are temporarily over-valued, and that price-to-earnings ratios will soon fall back to more normal levels [this is the ratio of stock prices to trend earnings]. However, if this is the basis for assuming that stocks will provide their historic rates of return in the future, it would be necessary to include a large decline in stock prices in the projections.”

Andrew probably missed it, but we did in fact have a large decline in stock prices (two actually) between 2000 and the present. That is why I am now confident that we can expect higher rates of return in the future. In other words, I have been 100 percent consistent in my projections of returns, what has changed is the market itself.

I appreciate Andrew’s efforts to remind everyone that I called the stock bubble back in 2000 (actually first in 1997).

Andrew Biggs, an economist at the American Enterprise Institute, is one of the more serious and careful people arguing conservative positions on policy issues. Nonetheless, he strikes out badly in trying to catch me in a contradiction. (Excuse the self-indulgence, consider this a carryover from my birthday boasts.)

Andrew has a blog post where he apparently believes that he has really got me [thanks gov wonk]. I have authored or co-authored several items recently on public pensions in which I argued that it is almost impossible to imagine scenarios in which pensions get returns on their stock holdings that are markedly worse than what they are assuming in their projections (e.g. here and here).

Andrew has my projected returns as averaging 8.9 percent in the current decade and 8.2 percent in the next two decades. (That’s not quite right, but close enough.) He then pulls out his gotcha, a paper from 2000 in which I projected stock returns of 3.4 percent for the first two decades and 3.5 percent for the 2030s. (In a note he points out that he forgot to add 2.8 percent for the inflation rate assumed by the Social Security trustees, whose assumptions provided the basis for my projections.)

So Andrew has me projected 8.9 percent returns and 8.2 percent returns when I was making projections of 6.4 percent and 6.5 percent back in 2000. Should I be wearing a paper bag over my head for the next year in shame?

Perhaps I should, but not because of Andrew’s discovery. In that 2000 paper I wrote:

“It is reasonable to believe … that stocks are temporarily over-valued, and that price-to-earnings ratios will soon fall back to more normal levels [this is the ratio of stock prices to trend earnings]. However, if this is the basis for assuming that stocks will provide their historic rates of return in the future, it would be necessary to include a large decline in stock prices in the projections.”

Andrew probably missed it, but we did in fact have a large decline in stock prices (two actually) between 2000 and the present. That is why I am now confident that we can expect higher rates of return in the future. In other words, I have been 100 percent consistent in my projections of returns, what has changed is the market itself.

I appreciate Andrew’s efforts to remind everyone that I called the stock bubble back in 2000 (actually first in 1997).

Given the failure of the economics profession to see the economic crisis coming or to devise an effective path forward, many people have come to question its competence and/or integrity. Somehow its assessments often seem to favor the rich. For example, economists can be counted on to get really hot under the collar over a 20-30 percent tariff barrier that is designed to temporarily protect manufacturing workers, but don't even notice that patent protection for prescription drugs raises their price by tens of thousands percent. Economists can't even seem to remember that in a system of floating exchange rates, like the one we have, a decline in the value of the dollar is supposed to be the remedy for a trade deficit. The NYT tells us that China's economists are equally incompetent and/or corrupt. It tells us that they are worried that the Chinese are not having enough kids: "Pressure to alter the policy [the one child policy] is building on other fronts as well, as economists say that China’s aging population and dwindling pool of young, cheap labor will be a significant factor in slowing the nation’s economic growth rate." Yes, that sounds like a real problem: "a dwindling pool of cheap labor." Any economist who complains about this is working for the people who want to employ cheap labor, he/she does not give a damn about the economy. Insofar as growth is a measure of anything, it is per capita growth that matters. Why would anyone be happier if the economy grew 20 percent, but population grew 50 percent? This is unambiguously bad for the country as a whole, even if there are some people who might benefit from being able to hire cheaper labor. Economists who are not employed by rich people understand that "cheap labor" means that lots of people are working for little money. This should not be a goal of any honest economist.
Given the failure of the economics profession to see the economic crisis coming or to devise an effective path forward, many people have come to question its competence and/or integrity. Somehow its assessments often seem to favor the rich. For example, economists can be counted on to get really hot under the collar over a 20-30 percent tariff barrier that is designed to temporarily protect manufacturing workers, but don't even notice that patent protection for prescription drugs raises their price by tens of thousands percent. Economists can't even seem to remember that in a system of floating exchange rates, like the one we have, a decline in the value of the dollar is supposed to be the remedy for a trade deficit. The NYT tells us that China's economists are equally incompetent and/or corrupt. It tells us that they are worried that the Chinese are not having enough kids: "Pressure to alter the policy [the one child policy] is building on other fronts as well, as economists say that China’s aging population and dwindling pool of young, cheap labor will be a significant factor in slowing the nation’s economic growth rate." Yes, that sounds like a real problem: "a dwindling pool of cheap labor." Any economist who complains about this is working for the people who want to employ cheap labor, he/she does not give a damn about the economy. Insofar as growth is a measure of anything, it is per capita growth that matters. Why would anyone be happier if the economy grew 20 percent, but population grew 50 percent? This is unambiguously bad for the country as a whole, even if there are some people who might benefit from being able to hire cheaper labor. Economists who are not employed by rich people understand that "cheap labor" means that lots of people are working for little money. This should not be a goal of any honest economist.
Steven Pearlstein, the Washington Post business columnist, often writes insightful pieces on the economy, not today. The thrust of his piece is that we all should be hopeful that a group of incredibly rich CEOs can engineer a coup. While the rest of us are wasting our time worrying about whether Barack Obama or Mitt Romney are sitting in the White House the next four years, Pearlstein tells us (approvingly) that these honchos are scurrying through back rooms in Washington trying to carve out a deficit deal. The plan is that we will get the rich folks' deal regardless of who wins the election. It is difficult to imagine a more contemptuous attitude toward democracy. The deal that this gang (led by Morgan Stanley director Erskine Bowles) is hatching will inevitably include some amount of tax increases and also large budget cuts. At the top of the list, as Pearlstein proudly tells us, are cuts to Social Security and Medicare. At a time when we have seen an unprecedented transfer of income to the top one percent, these deficit warriors are placing a top priority on snatching away a portion of Social Security checks that average $1,200 a month. Yes, the country needs this. The most likely cut to Social Security is a reduction in the annual cost of living adjustment of 0.3 percentage points. While that might sound trivial, the effect accumulates through time. After ten years, a typical check will be about 3 percent lower, after 20 years it will be 6 percent lower, and after 30 years it will be about 9 percent lower. Social Security amounts to 90 percent or more of the income for one-third of seniors. For this group, the proposed cut in benefits would be a considerably larger share of their income that the higher taxes faced by someone earning $300,000 a year as a result of the repeal of the Bush tax cuts on high income earners. The latter is supposed to be a big deal, therefore the proposed cuts to Social Security are also a big deal.
Steven Pearlstein, the Washington Post business columnist, often writes insightful pieces on the economy, not today. The thrust of his piece is that we all should be hopeful that a group of incredibly rich CEOs can engineer a coup. While the rest of us are wasting our time worrying about whether Barack Obama or Mitt Romney are sitting in the White House the next four years, Pearlstein tells us (approvingly) that these honchos are scurrying through back rooms in Washington trying to carve out a deficit deal. The plan is that we will get the rich folks' deal regardless of who wins the election. It is difficult to imagine a more contemptuous attitude toward democracy. The deal that this gang (led by Morgan Stanley director Erskine Bowles) is hatching will inevitably include some amount of tax increases and also large budget cuts. At the top of the list, as Pearlstein proudly tells us, are cuts to Social Security and Medicare. At a time when we have seen an unprecedented transfer of income to the top one percent, these deficit warriors are placing a top priority on snatching away a portion of Social Security checks that average $1,200 a month. Yes, the country needs this. The most likely cut to Social Security is a reduction in the annual cost of living adjustment of 0.3 percentage points. While that might sound trivial, the effect accumulates through time. After ten years, a typical check will be about 3 percent lower, after 20 years it will be 6 percent lower, and after 30 years it will be about 9 percent lower. Social Security amounts to 90 percent or more of the income for one-third of seniors. For this group, the proposed cut in benefits would be a considerably larger share of their income that the higher taxes faced by someone earning $300,000 a year as a result of the repeal of the Bush tax cuts on high income earners. The latter is supposed to be a big deal, therefore the proposed cuts to Social Security are also a big deal.
I guess it's childish name-calling time at the NYT. Hence Bill Keller tells readers that if you ask any "credible economist" you will get Keller's preferred solution to the budget. At the top of the list is "entitlement reforms." For those who don't know, "entitlement reforms" is Washington elite speak for cuts to Social Security and Medicare. They know that these programs are hugely popular, so the Washington elite crew use their little code word "entitlements," since they know that "entitlements" don't have nearly as much support. They also use "reform" since it sounds much nicer than "cuts." Of course the point is to cut Social Security and Medicare; Keller is simply not honest enough to say this to readers. Anyhow, let me just briefly explain why at least one non-credible economist doesn't support the cuts to Social Security and Medicare that former Senator Alan Simpson and Morgan Stanley director Erskine Bowles proposed. (Keller wrongly referred to their plan as a being a plan approved by their commission. This is not true, to be approved as a commission proposal a plan would have required the support of 14 of the 18 members of the commission.) The Bowles-Simpson plan would impose substantial cuts to Social Security benefits that would hit people already getting benefits. It would reduce the annual cost of living adjustment by 0.3 percent. This would lower the benefits that retirees receive by roughly 3 percent after 10 years, 6 percent after 20 years, and  9 percent after 30 years. This will be a serious hit to tens of millions of seniors who rely on Social Security for half or more of their income. Given that the average Social Security check is $1,200 a month, it is a bit hard to accept that these people should be in the center of our gunsights when we turn to deficit reduction.
I guess it's childish name-calling time at the NYT. Hence Bill Keller tells readers that if you ask any "credible economist" you will get Keller's preferred solution to the budget. At the top of the list is "entitlement reforms." For those who don't know, "entitlement reforms" is Washington elite speak for cuts to Social Security and Medicare. They know that these programs are hugely popular, so the Washington elite crew use their little code word "entitlements," since they know that "entitlements" don't have nearly as much support. They also use "reform" since it sounds much nicer than "cuts." Of course the point is to cut Social Security and Medicare; Keller is simply not honest enough to say this to readers. Anyhow, let me just briefly explain why at least one non-credible economist doesn't support the cuts to Social Security and Medicare that former Senator Alan Simpson and Morgan Stanley director Erskine Bowles proposed. (Keller wrongly referred to their plan as a being a plan approved by their commission. This is not true, to be approved as a commission proposal a plan would have required the support of 14 of the 18 members of the commission.) The Bowles-Simpson plan would impose substantial cuts to Social Security benefits that would hit people already getting benefits. It would reduce the annual cost of living adjustment by 0.3 percent. This would lower the benefits that retirees receive by roughly 3 percent after 10 years, 6 percent after 20 years, and  9 percent after 30 years. This will be a serious hit to tens of millions of seniors who rely on Social Security for half or more of their income. Given that the average Social Security check is $1,200 a month, it is a bit hard to accept that these people should be in the center of our gunsights when we turn to deficit reduction.

There are good paying jobs for unskilled people managing pension funds. Floyd Norris reports on how these folks, who get 6-figure salaries, expected to get 8 percent returns even when the price to trend earnings ratio in the stock market exceeded 20 and even 30.

People who know arithmetic could have explained to these managers that this would not be possible. Today many of these pensions are seriously underfunded.

There are good paying jobs for unskilled people managing pension funds. Floyd Norris reports on how these folks, who get 6-figure salaries, expected to get 8 percent returns even when the price to trend earnings ratio in the stock market exceeded 20 and even 30.

People who know arithmetic could have explained to these managers that this would not be possible. Today many of these pensions are seriously underfunded.

A Washington Post piece on German attitudes towards the crisis in the euro zone at one point refers to the high borrowing costs in Spain and Italy. It then tells readers:

“But in Germany’s view, yields on Spanish bonds — just above 7 percent as of Friday — are indeed with precedent, since Spain borrowed at rates well above 8 percent for most of the 1990s, touching 14 percent at one point. Italy had even higher borrowing costs than Spain in the 1990s.”

While the piece later notes that “many economists” say the comparison is misleading because Spain and Italy had higher inflation (much higher) and growth in the 1990s, this is in fact the view of all economists who know arithmetic. Economists focus on the real interest rate, the difference between the nominal interest rate and the inflation rate. Currently inflation in Spain and Italy is running near zero, which means that the nominal interest rates of above 7 percent translate into real interest rates above 7 percent.

By contrast, inflation in both countries averaged more than 5 percent for the first half of the 1990s. This means that a nominal interest rate of 8 percent would have translated into a real interest rate of around 3 percent.

If Germany has people in positions of responsibility who do not understand the concept of the real interest rate it would be very scary. That would be worthy of a major front page story.

A Washington Post piece on German attitudes towards the crisis in the euro zone at one point refers to the high borrowing costs in Spain and Italy. It then tells readers:

“But in Germany’s view, yields on Spanish bonds — just above 7 percent as of Friday — are indeed with precedent, since Spain borrowed at rates well above 8 percent for most of the 1990s, touching 14 percent at one point. Italy had even higher borrowing costs than Spain in the 1990s.”

While the piece later notes that “many economists” say the comparison is misleading because Spain and Italy had higher inflation (much higher) and growth in the 1990s, this is in fact the view of all economists who know arithmetic. Economists focus on the real interest rate, the difference between the nominal interest rate and the inflation rate. Currently inflation in Spain and Italy is running near zero, which means that the nominal interest rates of above 7 percent translate into real interest rates above 7 percent.

By contrast, inflation in both countries averaged more than 5 percent for the first half of the 1990s. This means that a nominal interest rate of 8 percent would have translated into a real interest rate of around 3 percent.

If Germany has people in positions of responsibility who do not understand the concept of the real interest rate it would be very scary. That would be worthy of a major front page story.

I don't often disagree with Paul Krugman these days but I do have to take him to task for buying into the "conservatives don't like government" line. In a blogpost he notes that a Republican health care bill in the House would take away funding for the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality and any economic research funded by the National Institutes of Health. He then concludes by commenting: "You sometimes hear conservatives saying that the role of government should be limited to the provision of public goods; obviously I don’t agree. But it turns out that they hate providing public goods, like research, too." Okay, there is a consistent pattern in the behavior of conservatives and it has nothing to do with a dislike of public goods or even a dislike of government intervention in the economy. What is the quintessential public good? That's right, the military. Do we see conservatives like Mitt Romney and Paul Ryan yelling about waste in the military and the need to pare it back? I surely haven't. So why are they willing to spend so much money on one set of public goods, the military, but hate the thought of spending relatively trivial sums on the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality or the economic research funded by the National Institutes of Health? Let's think for a moment about who benefits. Yes, defense contractors make lots of money selling overpriced and often useless hardware and services to the military. While private contractors may get some nickels and dimes out of the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality or economic research funded by the National Institutes of Health, you won't find the big bucks there. In fact, one result of the research funded by these two agencies might be that insurers, drug companies, medical equipment suppliers and other big corporate interests may find the usefulness or cost of their products called into question. That could lead to lower profits. In other words, the most obvious story here is not that conservatives are opposed to public goods. Rather they are opposed to public goods that could have the effect of less income being redistributed upward.
I don't often disagree with Paul Krugman these days but I do have to take him to task for buying into the "conservatives don't like government" line. In a blogpost he notes that a Republican health care bill in the House would take away funding for the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality and any economic research funded by the National Institutes of Health. He then concludes by commenting: "You sometimes hear conservatives saying that the role of government should be limited to the provision of public goods; obviously I don’t agree. But it turns out that they hate providing public goods, like research, too." Okay, there is a consistent pattern in the behavior of conservatives and it has nothing to do with a dislike of public goods or even a dislike of government intervention in the economy. What is the quintessential public good? That's right, the military. Do we see conservatives like Mitt Romney and Paul Ryan yelling about waste in the military and the need to pare it back? I surely haven't. So why are they willing to spend so much money on one set of public goods, the military, but hate the thought of spending relatively trivial sums on the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality or the economic research funded by the National Institutes of Health? Let's think for a moment about who benefits. Yes, defense contractors make lots of money selling overpriced and often useless hardware and services to the military. While private contractors may get some nickels and dimes out of the Agency for Healthcare Research and Quality or economic research funded by the National Institutes of Health, you won't find the big bucks there. In fact, one result of the research funded by these two agencies might be that insurers, drug companies, medical equipment suppliers and other big corporate interests may find the usefulness or cost of their products called into question. That could lead to lower profits. In other words, the most obvious story here is not that conservatives are opposed to public goods. Rather they are opposed to public goods that could have the effect of less income being redistributed upward.

The Post did readers a great service in providing another example of how the government makes rich people rich. The article is about how a set of drugs intended to anemia, turned out to be both ineffective and potentially harmful.

The two companies that had government-granted patent monopolies on these drugs, Amgen and Johnson & Johnson, gained tens of billions of revenue from these drugs over the last two decades. The article points out that they attempted to conceal evidence that their drugs could be harmful and used their political connections to get politicians to lobby the Food and Drug Administration on their behalf. They also designed a payments system that effectively paid off doctors to use large amounts of their drugs.

This is exactly the sort of corruption that economic theory predicts will result when the government puts an artificial barrier in the market (i.e. a patent monopoly) that allows companies to sell a product at hundreds or even thousands of times their cost of production. It might have been useful if the Post had included the views of an economist who could explain this point to readers.

The Post did readers a great service in providing another example of how the government makes rich people rich. The article is about how a set of drugs intended to anemia, turned out to be both ineffective and potentially harmful.

The two companies that had government-granted patent monopolies on these drugs, Amgen and Johnson & Johnson, gained tens of billions of revenue from these drugs over the last two decades. The article points out that they attempted to conceal evidence that their drugs could be harmful and used their political connections to get politicians to lobby the Food and Drug Administration on their behalf. They also designed a payments system that effectively paid off doctors to use large amounts of their drugs.

This is exactly the sort of corruption that economic theory predicts will result when the government puts an artificial barrier in the market (i.e. a patent monopoly) that allows companies to sell a product at hundreds or even thousands of times their cost of production. It might have been useful if the Post had included the views of an economist who could explain this point to readers.

Morning Edition had a segment on a change in public pension fund accounting that will show many funds have a much larger shortfall. The piece included comments from a Stanford business school professor, Joshua Rauh, that complained that the discount rate assumed by pension funds assumed that future pension fund returns will be like past returns.

Rauh’s statement to this effect is inaccurate, or at least incomplete. The main question mark in pension fund returns is the return on stock, which typically accounts for 60-70 percent of pension fund assets. While stock returns can fluctuate hugely year to year, over the long-term (like the 30-year time horizon of most pension funds) they are a relatively predictable function of current price to earnings ratios and the rate of growth of the economy.

Given current price to earnings ratios in the market, it would require an unprecedented economic collapse for the market to yield substantially lower returns than what pension funds are now assuming. Ruling out a complete economic collapse might be assuming that the future will be like the past, but this sort of extrapolation is pretty much impossible to avoid.

The piece also wrongly implied that the Governmental Accounting Standards Board (GASB) agreed with Rauh’s assessment in its proposed changes to accounting standards. This is not true. A pension fund that is fully funded using the 8.0 percent discount rate that Rauh criticized would not see any change in its funding status under the new GASB rules. Only pensions that are underfunded by the old accounting standard that would see a change in their calculated level of funding. 

Morning Edition had a segment on a change in public pension fund accounting that will show many funds have a much larger shortfall. The piece included comments from a Stanford business school professor, Joshua Rauh, that complained that the discount rate assumed by pension funds assumed that future pension fund returns will be like past returns.

Rauh’s statement to this effect is inaccurate, or at least incomplete. The main question mark in pension fund returns is the return on stock, which typically accounts for 60-70 percent of pension fund assets. While stock returns can fluctuate hugely year to year, over the long-term (like the 30-year time horizon of most pension funds) they are a relatively predictable function of current price to earnings ratios and the rate of growth of the economy.

Given current price to earnings ratios in the market, it would require an unprecedented economic collapse for the market to yield substantially lower returns than what pension funds are now assuming. Ruling out a complete economic collapse might be assuming that the future will be like the past, but this sort of extrapolation is pretty much impossible to avoid.

The piece also wrongly implied that the Governmental Accounting Standards Board (GASB) agreed with Rauh’s assessment in its proposed changes to accounting standards. This is not true. A pension fund that is fully funded using the 8.0 percent discount rate that Rauh criticized would not see any change in its funding status under the new GASB rules. Only pensions that are underfunded by the old accounting standard that would see a change in their calculated level of funding. 

Want to search in the archives?

¿Quieres buscar en los archivos?

Click Here Haga clic aquí