Article Artículo
Year-Over-Year Growth in Wages and Employees Cost Index, 2001-2016July 8, 2016
CEPR / July 08, 2016
Article Artículo
Employment Rebounds in June, but Unemployment Edges HigherJuly 8, 2016 (Jobs Byte)
Dean Baker / July 08, 2016
Article Artículo
This is a Test: What Kind of Democracy Do We Have in the United States?Mark Weisbrot / July 07, 2016
Article Artículo
E.J. Dionne Fights Nostalgia and Amnesia, but Succumbs to MyopiaCEPR / July 07, 2016
Article Artículo
Trade and Jobs In PennsylvaniaAdam Davidson had an interesting NYT Magazine piece on Donald Trump and the central Pennsylvania economy. His basic point, that Trump's proposals for high tariffs will not revitalize the region is undoubtedly correct, but there are a few points that should be made.
First, productivity and technological change has been far more important for jobs in manufacturing than trade, but that doesn't mean trade has not still been a big deal. We have seen rapid productivity growth in manufacturing through the whole post-war period, but the number of jobs in the sector remained roughly constant, with cyclical fluctuations, from the late 1960s until the end of the 1990s. Since the labor force was growing over this period, it did mean that the manufacturing share of employment was falling.
However, the absolute number of jobs plummeted at the start of the last decade as the trade deficit exploded. The drop was more than 20 percent even before the 2008 recession.
Jobs in Manufacturing
Source: Bureau of Labor Statistics.
This sharp decline in manufacturing employment had negative effects in many regions of the country, although it's possible that the impact in central Pennsylvania was less than in other manufacturing regions. Also, the threat of job loss, often due to trade, is an important factor affecting workers' bargaining power and therefore their ability to secure pay increases.
CEPR / July 07, 2016
Article Artículo
Latin America and the Caribbean
La OEA necesita un nuevo liderazgoMark Weisbrot / July 06, 2016
Article Artículo
Already Low Inflation Ticks DownwardSince the Fed first announced its 2 percent inflation target on January 25, 2012, inflation has consistently run too low. In fact, the Fed has undershot its target in 48 of the 51 months since its announcement.
The most recent data from the Consumer Price Index (CPI) show that inflation over the past year has been just 1.0 percent. Part of this weakness is due to the volatile energy (down 10.1 percent from one year ago) and food (up 0.7 percent) aspects of the index. The Fed typically pulls out these components and looks at the “core” CPI. This measure shows a somewhat higher rate of inflation with a modest increase over the last year.
CEPR and / July 05, 2016
Article Artículo
Quick Folks, How Big a Deal Is $300 Million a Year to Lithuania?CEPR / July 04, 2016
Article Artículo
Bill Gates to Fund Huge XPrize to End Austerity in EuropeDean Baker
Truthout, July 4, 2016
Dean Baker / July 04, 2016
Article Artículo
The Need for a Higher Valued Chinese CurrencyDean Baker
China/U.S. Focus, July 4, 2016
Dean Baker / July 04, 2016
Article Artículo
Washington Post Neglects to Mention Germany Is Responsible for Weak Economies Elsewhere in the EUCEPR / July 04, 2016
Article Artículo
NYT Is Badly Confused: President Obama Is Pushing Protectionism, Not Selling GlobalizationCEPR / July 04, 2016
Article Artículo
Paul Krugman on Trade and JobsPaul Krugman has again waded into trade and employment turf in his latest blog post. I agree completely with the post-Great Recession story where Krugman acknowledges that the trade deficit creates a demand gap that we have not been able to fill.
The problem is that fiscal policy is limited by a bizarre austerity cult that works to prevent larger budget deficits even though the economy clearly needs them to reach full employment levels of output. Monetary policy has been helpful, but with the Fed up against the zero lower bound there is not much more the Fed can do by way of traditional monetary policy to boost the economy. As a result, the trade deficit really does mean lost jobs.
Where I differ with Krugman is in his assessment that the trade deficit did not cost the economy jobs in the pre-recession period. He argues that we were pretty much at full employment in the period prior to the 2008 recession.
"Up through 2007 we basically had a Fed which raised rates whenever it thought the economy was overheating; in the absence of the China shock it would have raised rates sooner and faster..."
Just to refresh folks' memory, the unemployment rate was 4.0 percent as a year-round average in 2000. In the recovery, we bottomed out at 4.4 percent for several months in 2006 and 2007, although we didn't get back below 5.0 percent until the end of 2005. But the unemployment rate doesn't really tell the whole story.
The employment rate for prime age men (ages 25–54) peaked at 89.5 percent at the start of 2000. In the recovery, it never crossed 88.0 percent. When the recession hit at the end of 2007 it was at 87.2 percent, more than two full percentage points below its 2000 peak. This gap corresponds to a drop in employment among this group of more than 1 million.
CEPR / July 04, 2016
Article Artículo
David Brooks’ “Coming Political Realignment”: How Could it Happen?CEPR / July 02, 2016
Article Artículo
Neil Irwin Is Far Too Generous to Economists: They Only Care About Efficiency When the Policy Redistributes Income UpwardNeil Irwin raises the question of whether economists have been too single-minded in pushing efficiency, while ignoring issues of distribution. This is way, way too generous to economists. In fact, economists have been totally happy to ignore efficiency considerations when the inefficiencies redistribute income upward. This situation pops up all the time.
As I frequently point out in comments here and elsewhere, we protect doctors, dentists and other highly paid professionals from competition with their lower paid counterparts in the developing world or even other wealthy countries. We have maintained these protections even while our trade negotiators did everything they could to make steel workers and textile workers compete against their low-paid counterparts in Mexico, China, and other developing countries.
This protectionism is obviously inefficient and cost U.S. consumers more than $100 billion a year in higher medical bills and other costs. Yet economists act really dumb when questioned about it. Apparently, it never occurred to them that competent doctors could be trained in Mexico, India, or even Germany. Sorry folks, economists don't give a damn about efficiency in this case. They want to protect the income of highly paid professionals.
CEPR / July 02, 2016